A literature review on the design and implementation of central bank digital currencies

  • Research Article
  • Open access
  • Published: 24 January 2024
  • Volume 18 , pages 197–225, ( 2024 )

Cite this article

You have full access to this open access article

  • Huseyin Oguz Genc   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-5997-1763 1 &
  • Soichiro Takagi 1  

1752 Accesses

1 Altmetric

Explore all metrics

Within the last five years, research on Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) has increased with increased momentum. Particular events, such as the growth of private digital currencies, Facebook’s attempt to release a stablecoin, the long-term development of Chinese CBDC, and Covid-19, are the leading causes for this growing significant interest. Most recently, the interest converged in more specific design and implementation directions. Many scholars show particular interest in account-based retail CBDCs with interest-bearing capabilities. In contrast, few others urge caution by favoring a wholesale model that is representative of the setting of the current financial system. Unsurprisingly, the primary source of such literature stems from global financial institutions and their close central banking networks. Academia and research institutions have recently increased their focus on the potential economic and social impacts of such purported design choices. As specific design principles for CBDCs have started to take shape, the policy objectives of implementing different CBDC designs are studied from the perspective of benefits and risks. These trade-offs are either generic or related to macroeconomic and financial stability implications. Evidence exists that purported generic benefits can often be achieved without CBDCs, while the purported monetary and fiscal policy benefits rely on theoretical results that lack real-world data. Some of the risks could be amplified depending on CBDC design choices. Theoretical and alternative literature is reviewed along with the evidence from use-case applications to spot the possible shortcomings in the current stage of the design and implementation literature of CBDCs. The scope is limited to the impact on economic policies and the relevant potential socioeconomic impact. The results show that further research and debate are needed from a multidisciplinary perspective.

Similar content being viewed by others

research paper about central bank

Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs): The Global Development Trends and Prospects for Use as Investment Objects

research paper about central bank

Towards Optimal Technological Solutions for Central Bank Digital Currencies

research paper about central bank

The Future of Money: Central Bank Digital Currencies

Michael Lloyd

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

Introduction

Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) are a topic that has gained the attention of researchers with increasing momentum in recent years. The research landscape has rapidly developed with a strong interest in upgrading public digital monetary infrastructures.

As research on CBDCs increased, specific topics have trended among researchers. Such issues have clustered around core arguments that either indicate certain events as stimulants for CBDC developments or attempt to assess the implications of introducing CBDCs. Concurrently, the institutional patterns and their preferred political choices became apparent. Many researchers have conducted in-depth research to understand the associated tradeoffs and the reasoning for those preferred CBDC design choices.

Among the narratives that have matured around scholarship on CBDCs, the design and implementation discussions have become one of the most important topics before the global-scale rollout of these new digital currency systems. This paper provides a detailed review of the fundamental debates in this realm and its relevant subjects. Another focus is to investigate whether there are skewed preferences for particular design choices and the potential reasons behind those tendencies. The findings are classified within the scope of the expected impact of CBDC design and implementation on the macro policy and financial stability. Meanwhile, alternative discussions and practical implications are also covered to draw comprehensive and diverse results. Another effort of this review is to identify critical points that the existing literature have not addressed thus far.

The paper will proceed in the following order. The next section offers a summary of the results and research methodology of the review. Section three covers an overview of the generic research on CBDCs that begins with an introduction of relevant research background. It continues with a classification of the generic design features of CBDCs and winds up with a survey of the frequently mentioned benefits, risks, and implementation costs. The fourth section deals with the theoretical results, which consist of the mainstream central banking approach to the potential macro policy and financial stability implications of different CBDC design and implementation choices. The next part of the section provides alternative research methods, covering historical discussions relevant to private and public digital currencies. The paper continues by reviewing the findings of the existing CBDC case studies that have reached the implementation stage. The final section concludes with a summary of the contributions and limitations of the research.

Summary of results and methodology

This section consists of two parts. The first provides a high-level summary of the research results, while the second part describes the methodology used in the review.

Summary of results

In a high-level overview, we identify the current state of the literature as predominantly theoretical. The leading research efforts on CBDCs stem from international institutes such as the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) and International Monetary Fund (IMF). Central bank staff of most leading economies and well-known research institutes are in arms-distance with these international institutions and are similarly active in parallel research efforts. Most of these researchers study the theoretical research on the macro policy and financial stability impact of CBDCs’ which will be covered in section four. Macroeconomic studies focus on the potential functional gains for unconventional monetary and fiscal policies and other topics, such as, welfare effects, and price stability. Financial stability research builds on the central theme of how CBDC design choices may impact financial intermediaries and the global financial order.

As a complimentary analysis, we identify the critical events highlighted within the current narratives in CBDCs research that are either implicitly or explicitly mentioned as a stimulant for the recent increase in the research and development of CBDCs. We identify four key events. These are Covid-19, China's leading position in CBDC development, the rise of Bitcoin, and the attempt by Meta (previously Facebook) to release a global digital stablecoin, namely Libra. From the 86 covered pieces of literature, the keywords “China” and “Bitcoin” are, respectively, featured in 48 and 41 of the works, whereas “Libra” and “Covid” are mentioned in 37 and 25 of those pieces. In light of these events, the political motivations for a global push for CBDC implementations could be more specifically explained. One clear trend in the literature shows that although scholars often mention Bitcoin, it is not taken as an equally strong reason for the sudden spurt in CBDC research and development. At the same time, Libra is deemed to have more of a direct stimulant effect.

There is a general tendency among many scholars to take certain innate traits of CBDCs as given benefits. However, there is abundant evidence that most of the generic benefits associated with CBDCs can be achieved with legacy financial technologies. Therefore, such claims are false or require tangible data to prove their points. For example, the decline in cash usage is asserted as a deterministic fact that mandates the need for developing advanced digital payment systems. None of the literature covered in this review has provided data about cash payments to support their claims. However, some studies do not imply a dramatic reduction in cash usage as it remains a ubiquitous means of payment in many economies [ 57 ].

Meanwhile, the offshore availability of reserve currencies in cash complicates the situation further [ 43 ]. Therefore, the methodological and scientific arguments of such claims should be debated. Another topic that accumulates strong assertions is financial inclusion. Besides the fact that no tangible data could be found in this review to support the claim that CBDCs can improve financial inclusion, the recent rollout of the Nigerian CBDC, e-Naira, has shown contrary evidence, suggesting that socioeconomic stability may be jeopardized under the disguise of financial inclusion objectives. Therefore, further research seems necessary to scrutinize the alleged benefits of CBDCs.

It is important to note that the way e-Naira’s launch was politically enforced provides clear implications that the most relevant research on CBDCs is more likely to fall within the scopes of globalism and political economy. Such matters are not directly within the scope of this paper. Nevertheless, some essential literature was surveyed to achieve the objective of a comprehensive review. In [ 31 ] underlines such a trajectory for the global financial system by highlighting that technological developments provide an opportunity to build new multipolar reserve currencies in the long term. A fundamental assertion is that such events could ameliorate the balance sheet implications of the unipolar reserve currency setting that is currently in place. The new system can help prevent disrupting the incumbent reserve currencies by creating network externalities. Another critical claim is that the adoption of CBDCs could grow through the usefulness of such currencies as a medium of exchange in international payments. In [ 47 ] reports the ongoing work within the body of G20 to establish a multipolar setting that focuses on cross-border payments. The process is proceeding quickly from its early stages as the goal is establishing common standards and some adoption within this decade. Discussions on establishing regional digital currencies other than the digital Euro are also prevalent, as [ 54 ] proposes issuing a common digital currency in Asia by the early stages of Covid-19. The authors indicate that the primary objective of such a currency would also serve the purpose of settling cross-border trade payments.

There is an overwhelming focus within the scope of central banking research to comprehend the potential functional gains of CBDCs for monetary and fiscal policy purposes. A couple of these functions are implementing negative real interest rates and introducing programmable money. Such a trend makes perfect sense as central bankers are reaching towards introducing a very significant technology. However, there needs to be more focus on the theoretical implications of CBDCs under a persistently high inflation environment. This topic is relevant within the current economic realities and may provide a rational approach to why CBDCs will be adopted without any resistance. In this respect, another important point that is abundantly clear within the reviewed literature is that public opinion is, by and large, ignored. Some central bankers propose potentially disruptive changes to how society interfaces with money, such as eliminating cash and central programming of what people can do with their money. Therefore, more research is needed to understand the perception of the public on the matter.

In the following, the detailed results of this research are presented in four categories. First, the generic research on CBDCs will be inquired. Next category deals with the mainstream theoretical research on the potential macro policy and financial stability implications of CBDCs; yet also extends into alternative topics, such as the indispensable role of central bank money in payment networks, Footnote 1 currency competition, and private and public money coexistence schemes. The last category is dedicated to the existing case studies.

Research methodology

This review conducts discourse analysis. A keyword search on Google Scholar and ProQuest was conducted as a first step. Based on the results, articles within the scope of economic policy studies with the highest citation numbers on Google Scholar and higher impact metrics on ProQuest were selected. Next, backward and forward snowballing was done to identify a group of the most cross-referenced works, and the articles irrelevant to the general scopes of either economic policies or design or implementation were eliminated. The remaining literature was reviewed, seven main themes were designated, then classified into three groups. The third group consolidated alternative research topics, which were purposefully carried out to avoid potential research bias. The evaluated literature was primarily limited to peer-reviewed articles, research reports of financial and economic research institutions, and other relevant academic material.

Overview of the generic research on CBDCs

This section begins with a simple overview of the background of CBDC research and continues with a summary of the core design features established around the scope of CBDCs. A comprehensive survey of the generic benefits, risks, and costs associated with implementing these novel digital currencies is carried out in the latter part.

Background on CBDC research

The earliest mention of CBDCs is traced back to 2014 when Zhou Xiaochuan, the governor of the People’s Bank of China (PBoC) of the time, expressed the need to study the possibility of issuing a central bank digital currency [ 63 ]. Bank of England entered the discussion in 2015 by promoting research on the costs and benefits of a new form of central bank money that could extend the holdership directly to businesses and individuals [ 24 ].

Several studies compile a set of definitions for CBDCs [ 62 , 83 ], while [ 70 ] conducts a literature review on the topic, which provides various definitions according to the potential design characteristics. The survey of different works shows a consensus on a clear description of CBDCs has yet to be reached. As a narrow definition, CBDCs are digital representations of sovereign currencies. In this regard, CBDCs differ from cash, the central bank liability in physical form. In other words, they are poised to become digital liabilities of central banks and are envisioned as the core component of national reserve money systems [ 42 ].

Meanwhile, in the broader sense, the set design choices can alter the definition depending on several characteristics, such as extending CBDCs to retail use cases and adding programmability features. If the households are direct holders of the CBDC, it would be a digital currency of cash-like characteristics that would instead represent outside money [ 68 ]. Yet, unlike the physical control of cash by the individual, the oversight of the digital ledger will be limited in the hands of central banks and trusted parties.

In [ 20 ] classify different forms of money according to their control structures, as shown in Fig.  1 . They categorize these structures based on three features such as (1) representation (physical vs. virtual), (2) transaction handling (centralized vs. decentralized), and (3) money creation (monopoly vs. competitive). According to this definition, commercial bank deposits are virtual, like CBDCs, and they only exist as electronic records in the accounting system. However, since commercial banks compete for deposits, which they subsequently use for credit creation, the monetary form of a CBDC depends on whether the transaction handling is designed to replicate the existing bank deposit system.

figure 1

Source : Reproduced from [ 20 ]

Control structure of CBDCs vs. other types of currencies.

So far, most CBDCs are still in the trial phase. According to the CBDC Tracker of the Atlantic Council, eleven nations have already launched their CBDC projects, while twenty-one active pilots and thirty-two ongoing development projects are in the making. In total, a hundred and thirty countries are currently tracked. Footnote 2 Central banks usually publish whitepapers explaining the digital currency’s intended purpose.

Since there are many retail CBDC pilots, the research on the potential impact of CBDCs is highly theoretical [ 67 ]. A variety of scopes alternating according to the design characteristics are studied. Nevertheless, there is a general acceptance that retail CBDCs will become a reality as the future of payment agents. Therefore, the specific design choices required for their implementation will differ from a wholesale CBDC system that would instead replicate the existing financial system.

Generic design features of CBDCs

The BIS provides one of the earlier attempts among international financial institutions to issue a guideline for the essential design attributes [ 16 ]. Many later iterations have followed a similar framework. In essence, purported design choices are theoretical, yet the extent of the debate around some characteristics has become sophisticated over recent years.

Since the early phases of the design research for CBDCs, three fundamental debates revolve around the design models. The first of these models is the distribution model of CBDCs, which refers to either a retail or wholesale distribution model. A retail CBDC is a direct central bank liability, similar to cash. At the same time, the wholesale model, by default, means that the CBDC is distributed through the intermediaries in the financial system. In [ 5 ] survey the literature on the economics of retail CBDCs that study the implications of CBDCs on the financial system and policy-related issues.

Next comes the distribution model, directly related to the operating model. This function determines whether the distribution will be through intermediaries, namely the distribution of a wholesale CBDC through banks and payment system providers (PSPs) or a combination of direct/indirect operating models. It is essential to understand that an intermediated wholesale distribution prevents non-financial parties from directly executing transactions with the central banks. This setup is analogous to the current system in which accredited financial institutions, by and large, are the only parties with exclusive access to the balance sheet of central banks. Most research on CBDC design choices aims to find an optimal design to avoid the disintermediation of banks. Nevertheless, there is a strong urge to experiment with retail CBDCs to understand their potential implications on the intermediation role of banks and PSPs.

Another fundamental discussion on CBDC design is related to the access mechanism. The access design is contingent on the distribution and operating models yet procures options based on the technical grounds of how the consumers will interface with the CBDC ledger. Widely discussed options are token-based, account-based, or a combination of both, referred to as the hybrid model. The token-based model is reminiscent of digital currencies such as Bitcoin, which may provide anonymous peer-to-peer payments. Many researchers highlight that the token-based access model may provide privacy to users. On the other hand, an account-based retail CBDC model may allow individuals and corporations to open an account at the central bank ledgers, which on the contrary, is directly linked to their identities.

In [ 36 ] present a survey of these design choices for CBDCs, provided in Table  1 . Based on this categorization, most of the material reviewed in this paper falls under a particular design set. In [ 7 ] provide a comprehensive design study on the technical considerations of CBDCs, such as ledger infrastructure and identity management. In [ 1 ] focus on the identity scheme integration into CBDCs per se, which may get a lot more attention soon. Neither of these topics is included within the scope of this paper, yet they are among the most crucial subjects to study to have an in-depth understanding of the design and implementation process of CBDCs.

Benefits, risks, and costs for CBDCs

This section reviews the literature on the potential benefits and risks of prospective CBDC implementations from a generic perspective. A summary is provided in Table  2 . Lastly, a discussion on the potential costs of CBDCs is also included. The disintermediation of conventional financial institutions, a critical subject of risk associated with CBDCs, is covered in detail in the next section.

The generic benefits that are expected by the introduction of CBDCs can be simplified into three categories: political benefits, technical benefits, and social benefits. At the top of the political benefits, many studies focus on the potential advantages of CBDCs over cash and bank deposits. The primarily expected usefulness against cash is the potential broadening of the tax base, which is a parallel argument to the public sector gaining the ability to execute more efficient compliance on anti-money laundering (AML) processes. There is a firm conviction among researchers that the anonymous nature of cash makes it a disadvantageous tool for preventing tax evasion. In [ 30 ] summarizes the often-cited potential benefits and risks of an account-based retail CBDC model. However, the argument that governments can improve AML enforcement needs a reality check. The current inefficiencies in AML policies are prevalent [ 64 ], yet none of the covered literature alludes to this point for supporting their improved AML prevention case for CBDCs. For example, shadow economies may shift into using privacy-focused cryptocurrencies, rendering the case of an enhanced execution of AML policies useless.

The technical benefits of CBDCs require a sophisticated technical discussion. Thus, this subject is primarily out of the scope of this paper. In [ 75 ] underscores the variety of electronic systems in the United States for wholesale and retail payments. They purport that the economic contribution of a CBDC might be limited without enough demand for such a digital infrastructure. Meanwhile, financial technology (FinTech) applications are already widely used in many locations without the active operational involvement of governments. The potential technical efficiency improvements, such as low-cost instant payment settlements, have already been achieved in many jurisdictions worldwide.

Financial inclusion is often mentioned as a social benefit of introducing CBDCs, assuming that the government provides better access to the populations that do not have access to financial services. In [ 8 ] studies a model where CBDCs can be designed to oblige banks to compete for customer deposits, which is expected to improve financial inclusion. There needs to be a clear elaboration on how CBDCs can enable such a competition to increase financial inclusion.

Another political motivation for implementing CBDCs becomes even more ambiguous as governments try to limit the growing power of FinTech companies. China is imposing stringent controls on the local FinTech giants, and the adverse global reaction against Libra has shown that governments have discontent with the excessive power of Big Tech. The logic behind such policies may be residing on financial stability concerns, which will be covered in detail in section four.

The most anticipated case for CBDCs is the potential improvements they are expected to introduce for cross-border payments. In [ 41 ] discusses the viability of interoperable CBDCs for cross-border payments. In [ 22 ] argues that a competitive foreign exchange conversion layer should be built on top of domestic CBDC infrastructures to improve cross-border payments. The authors analyze the validity of Bitcoin, stablecoins, and settlement systems operated by legacy financial technologies to take on intermediary roles. They claim that domestically interlinked payment systems should be allowed to compete with CBDCs to see if the private sector can develop more promising solutions. Also, some markets are large enough to require the private sector’s contribution, per the authors’ views. Recent developments support this popular opinion, as [ 23 ] Footnote 3 and [ 48 ] mention that China's public and private–public partnership initiatives have started cross-border payment trials.

Bank for International Settlements’ role is central to cross-border settlement trials with CBDCs. In [ 14 ] go to length to conceptualize a multi-CBDC cross-border payment system framework, which can either represent the existing banking system or radically change the infrastructure through a single infrastructure and rulebook. While the current system is expected to work in a hybrid wholesale model, the paper asserts that an integrated approach could allow central banks to combine retail CBDCs with a direct operating model. However, a practical deliberation of how such national-scale compromises could be feasible is yet to be determined. The authors are critical of Libra, as they deem the currency to increase the risk of currency substitution while admitting that CBDCs alone are insufficient to prevent the phenomenon as currency digitalization is likely to worsen the outlook for economies with weak currencies. Nevertheless, the paper purports a paradigm of national CBDC networks that coexist in a more globally interlinked system. Economic networks that consist of actors with higher trade and remittance interlinkages may work on more modular monetary alliances, such as regional or strategic currency coalitions.

As a possible solution to the credible neutrality of setting common technical and legal standards to multi-CBDC settlement networks, a most recent project by the BIS considers interfacing CBDCs with established private stablecoin conversion networks in the cryptocurrency industry [ 18 ]. While the national networks may allow modular access to domestic participants, the protocol-level design can be implemented with an interoperable infrastructure that interfaces with international liquidity protocols. This setup enables direct settlements between the participants of different CBDC networks through the desired unit of account as long as they can assure technical interoperability with an off-shore liquidity protocol. Once technical and legal standards start shaping out, such a mechanism seems interesting as the future outlook of how private–public networks may interface, which includes considerations for the interaction between CBDCs and stablecoins.

The case of cross-border payments, in particular, shows that it is essential to underscore once more that a technical discussion is necessary to achieve a comprehensive understanding of the potential improvements of CBDCs over the existing digital payment systems. Although such topics are beyond the scope of this paper, this review acknowledges the difficulty of running a design-related discussion without extending the research area to technical grounds.

CBDC implementations are expected to have potential risks. Based on their relevancy, these risks can be narrowed down to the same three categories, like the benefits. The political issues governments may face during the design and implantation of CBDCs point to a lack of regulatory expertise and higher-than-ideal government involvement in the economy. Meanwhile, technical vulnerabilities and entrenched design mistakes are some other prominent risks. The social perils are loss of financial privacy and potential loss of funds [ 7 ].

The Bank for International Settlements strongly advocates an account-based retail CBDC despite underscoring the privacy and security risks of implementing CBDCs [ 17 ]. By attaching a digital ID as an online identification service, the Bank argues that users may benefit from a wide range of financial services while upholding protection against fraud and identity theft. However, there is overwhelming evidence about database infringements that have already exposed personally identifiable information about billions of people worldwide. Footnote 4 There is also extensive data from private cryptocurrency applications that achieving the security of funds in digital platforms contains high risk. Footnote 5 Different from identification data, the public opinion on governments to run secure digital payment schemes may diminish at a broader scale due to loss of funds.

[ 2 ] provide a detailed outlook on the potential risks of using direct operating mechanisms and advise central banks to adopt a more hybrid approach to avoid reputational risks. Despite much theoretical analysis, the practical evidence for validating or falsifying such benefits and risks is limited. In [ 67 ] asserts that the research on CBDCs is too theoretical and that more pilot projects are needed to measure the real-world impact of CBDCs. They refer to the feedback from Israel and Danish central banks, which have reportedly yet to see convincing benefits for replacing the legacy financial infrastructures with CBDCs. In [ 69 ] provides a comprehensive discussion on whether the financial inclusion benefits of CBDCs are as sound as they are claimed to be.

In [ 70 ] reviews the potential costs of issuing a central bank digital currency. The author refers to possible scenarios of increasing credit costs. The author also refers to [ 82 ] the likely costs of issuing a CBDC for public use, which can theoretically lead to cost savings for currency distribution. In contrast, new hardware and security costs, such as network setup and maintenance costs, need to be clarified regarding the costs of public spending. Meanwhile, further investment is required in fraud detection and prevention of phishing attacks to ensure consumer protection to avoid inflicting costs on users in the form of lost funds.

Another cost incurred is associated with adopting CBDC payment systems [ 37 ]. The cost of hardware infrastructure to work with CBDC applications can extend to various agencies, such as merchants, mobile operators, users, and governments, potentially making adopting CBDCs costly. Such issues can particularly slow down the adoption curve if financial costs are higher for merchants and users compared to using cash and existing payment systems.

Lastly, the introduction of CBDCs may have intangible costs. Since CBDCs may herald a cashless society, many scholars claim that eliminating cash from circulation may have significant socioeconomic consequences, particularly underscoring privacy concerns. Existing evidence shows that privacy concerns are already prominent [ 9 ]. Footnote 6 Meanwhile, broader adoption of fewer CBDC protocols may amplify the attack vector against a developing financial system. This threat may lead to significant social consequences when a lack of a physical medium of exchange serves as a unit of account. A potential cyberattack can erode the public trust in the public money network and harm the robustness of economic activity by undermining the payment function of CBDCs.

Theoretical results on CBDCs

This section provides the results of the theoretical literature. The first part delves into the mainstream approach that primarily consists of macroeconomic and financial stability works. The second part covers the literature that is relevant to economic policies and CBDC design and implementation considerations yet falls outside the scope of the defined mainstream approach.

Mainstream approach

The central themes of this part are the theoretical research on monetary and fiscal policies and financial stability, which are covered in two parts. The first part probes the potential macroeconomic impact of implementing varying CBDC designs, focusing on tentative improvements for unconventional monetary and fiscal policy applications, welfare effects, and price stability policies. The second part narrows down the focus on the issue of how CBDC designs may impact financial stability. A previous literature review by the Federal Reserve [ 30 ] was used as a critical piece, while another recent article by [ 53 ] also provides a more updated literature review focused on similar themes.

Macroeconomic impact

A frequently underscored political benefit is the flexible monetary policy improvements of interest-bearing CBDCs. [ 26 ] argues that CBDCs can satisfy all essential functions of money: a nearly costless medium of exchange, a secure store of value, and a stable unit of account. The paper reviews various theoretical works on how central banks may lose monetary control and macroeconomic stability and how a CBDC may answer such systemic risks. A critical discussion revolves around the potential of utilizing interest-bearing CBDCs to break below the Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) Footnote 7 during severe adverse shocks. The claim is that central banks can use account-based CBDCs to avoid being squeezed by the ZLB limitation, Footnote 8 which could help them circumvent controversial lender-of-last-resort practices such as quantitative easing. Committing to a transparent and credible monetary policy framework, a strong sentiment toward validating price-level targeting might benefit macroeconomic stability. However, it is politically challenging to implement such a CBDC model under the current financial regime as individuals would hoard cash, particularly in developed economies. This situation would be equivalent to a bank run; therefore, achieving a completely cashless economy is necessary for adopting an interest-bearing CBDC model that can break below the zero lower bound.

In [ 29 ] assesses a practical use case for CBDCs and their implications on the ZLB. The paper contends that the central bank can use a more direct helicopter money function, which would be delivered to CBDC accounts of households. Such a tool would seek to achieve a more direct monetary policy transmission on prices and the real economy, particularly when central banks meet the ZLB limitation. The result would be the replacement of asset purchase programs used for price stability objectives during economic shocks, simultaneously showing a reverse effect on the increasing wealth inequality caused by the same unconventional policies.

In [ 65 ] argue that negative nominal interest rates and helicopter money can be more impactful, thanks to CBDCs, yet maintain that central banks can still implement such policy tools without their introduction. The paper’s main findings suggest that assuming a universally accessible, freely convertible, and interest-bearing CBDC design choice, central banks can maintain the current monetary policy practices without much practical change. The paper also argues that CBDC policy rate transmission to the secondary lending market and the real economy would be more robust.

The purported use-case of direct payments to households may be attractive to governments, particularly under the current economic outlook with weakening demand, Footnote 9 all-time high youth unemployment, Footnote 10 and global wealth imbalances. Footnote 11 By implementing programmability into such digital money vouchers, some governments may aim to engineer the effective demand to enforce demand-side policies. Footnote 12 Such an objective, however, would stir up another dispute about the duties of governments and central banks potentially becoming exceedingly interventional in the economy. Meanwhile, [ 49 , 58 , 59 ] show that Covid-19 stimulants' data resembling such policies did not achieve the desired outcomes.

In [ 32 ] suggests that central banks should focus on money supply growth instead of only taking interest rates as the focal point. They argue that McCallum’s monetary policy rule is better suited than Taylor’s rule to understand the theoretical impact of CBDCs. The authors assert that their approach can help central banks monitor money aggregates and the inflationary effect of financial innovation more effectively. They explore the tentative inflationary impact of CBDCs based on the historical behavior of the velocity of circulation. Their results indicate that CBDCs need not produce higher inflation, yet policy considerations regarding the potential design attributes exist. One particular issue highlighted is the operating model. If central banks decide on a direct operating mechanism, the authors argue that such policies may lead to further cost reduction of financial services that households receive.

Using a structural New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) framework with an explicit velocity term, [ 52 ] explore the potential implications of a Central Bank Digital Currency (CBDC) issuance on aggregate fluctuations in the Indonesian economy. The study finds that a 10% decrease in money velocity, facilitated by a CBDC issuance, would reduce the inflation rate by 0.6–1.7%. The authors highlight the importance of considering money velocity for policy deliberations. The study also indicates that a larger-scale model is necessary to achieve more accurate projections on the potential impact of a CBDC issuance on aggregate fluctuations and the conduct of monetary policy.

It is essential to note that none of these studies mainly deal with a scenario where inflation remains sticky in the long run. Therefore, this subject is identified as an essential missing subject within the existing literature, and further research is necessary. In a high-emission scenario in the long term, central banks might offer CBDCs as the only option for inflation protection. In such a scenario, although adoption may not be mandatory, high levels of indirect taxing serve would as a pseudo-enforced policy.

In [ 19 ] study the long-run macroeconomic effects of a universally-accessible and interest-bearing central bank digital currency issued against government bonds and limited in nature against competing with bank deposits as a medium of exchange. They run a New Keynesian dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model in a closed economy to find that interest rates and distortionary taxes decrease, leading to a 3% increase in GDP. They claim that countercyclical policy for CBDCs can serve as an alternative monetary policy tool that stabilizes the business cycle when the economy faces a liquidity demand shock. Bank lending increases during such times, assuming the central bank can alter the interest rate on the CBDC and arbitrarily adjust the quantity of issuance of the CBDC.

In [ 85 ] studies the welfare-increasing policy rate conditions under which CBDCs can be run as a narrow banking facility that competes with private bank deposits while serving as a privacy-enabling payment option. In [ 37 ] finds that welfare may be lower when cash and an interest-bearing CBDC are simultaneously available and perfectly convertible. Unless the cost of carrying CBDC is less than cash, CBDC is under-utilized in a co-existence scheme.

In [ 33 ] make a contrarian argument that introducing an interest-bearing CBDC can increase bank intermediation if the central bank introduces competition to the lending market by implementing optimal CBDC deposit rates, which would intuitively increase deposits and lower loan rates. However, the empirical findings do not provide feedback on the desired welfare effect of introducing CBDC-induced competition on the monopoly of the banking sector [ 8 ].

In [ 56 ] run a money search model to study the impact of a retail CBDC introduction on interest rates, bank lending, output, and welfare. The study focuses on the policy trade-offs for CBDC designs that simultaneously compete with physical currency or bank deposits. Issuing a cash-like CBDC is desirable only if the volume of cash transactions is high. Meanwhile, a deposit-like CBDC may crowd out bank deposits; however, such an attribute may be desirable when credit market frictions are moderate and productive investment opportunities are rare. If a CBDC competes with cash and bank deposits simultaneously, the central bank becomes subject to a single interest rate restriction on a universally accessible digital currency. The results often show improvement in aggregate welfare.

In [ 4 ] seek an optimal design for a CBDC in a linear-city setup where participants can choose among cash, CBDC, and bank deposits based on their perceived levels of risk and privacy. The critical design choices for their CBDC model are based on whether it bears interest and resembles cash as an anonymous payment agent. The more CBDCs are designed similarly to either one, the more likely it is to crowd out that respective financial agent. However, if central banks choose between the two, they would opt for protecting intermediation, as the paper argues that increasing lending frictions of a deposit-like CBDC could dampen lending activities. This problem results in choosing a cash-like design choice, leading to cash disappearance if network effects are reached with a non-interest-bearing CBDC. Therefore, the authors argue that central banks should apply negative interest on CBDCs to ensure that demand for cash usage stays intact to maximize welfare effects by sustaining the most comprehensive variety of payment instruments.

Without featuring a bank run scenario, [ 76 ] run a nominal version of [ 38 ]. The study lies at the intersection of macroeconomic and financial stability discussions, thus presented as the last work to be reviewed in this part. The results demonstrate that central banks which offer token-based CBDC accounts (with anonymous payments) can achieve at most two of the three goals among the efficient allocation of resources, price stability, and financial stability.

Financial stability

This part differentiates financial stability from macro policy considerations by segregating the literature on whether introducing CBDCs would disrupt the legacy financial system. Particular topics of interest are covered, such as bank disintermediation, bank runs, currency substitution, and destabilizing effects of cross-border or regional economic interdependencies. Many researchers seek to outline conditions in which such disruptions may occur and the extent of the potential impact on banks and payment systems.

Most of the reviewed literature does not cover the scenario in which the negative interest rate policies could impact consumer behavior in ways that could negatively impact financial stability. Assuming that social awareness of negative nominal rates is negligibly low, the desired policy goals may backfire due to diminishing consumer confidence as individuals could take riskier bets in the face of negative rates. Thus, such scenarios need to be studied extensively, particularly concerning more speculative investment vehicles.

In [ 60 ] discuss the balance sheet implications of introducing CBDCs and the necessary design qualities to minimize the risk of bank runs or disintermediation. Possible scenarios on how bank deposits may shift to CBDC accounts are presented with a comprehensive thought exercise for the proposed design principles. Based on their analysis, they find a set of core design principles: adjustable interest rate, non-convertibility against reserves, non-convertibility of bank deposits into CBDCs on-demand, and the exclusive limitation of issuance of CBDCs against government securities. The model also indicates the risk of unacceptable negative interest rates in the short or long term.

In [ 21 ] analyzes the potential of negative interest rates to fail at creating the desired stabilizing economic impact. The author offers a two-tiered remuneration approach to mitigate the effects of economic shocks when the central banks need to implement negative rates. The first tier is the retail CBDCs used by households, and the interest rate on these holdings would be more attractive to avoid the risk of bank runs. Beyond a specific limit of CBDC holdings, each additional unit held in the non-household accounts would be subject to diminishing returns. Also, commercial bank liquidity may be further affected depending on the payment services central bank accounts may offer. The ability to execute online payments via central bank accounts may reduce the importance of the larger banks in a financial system that pursues liquidity concentration.

In [ 13 ] draft their proposal on a minimally invasive CBDC. The focus is on eliminating the potential risk of disintermediation for the banking sector. The outcome claims CBDCs should be designed as a direct claim on the central bank, like cash. The functional model architecture should be intermediated or hybrid to support such a system, while the CBDC should not be interest-bearing. This design aims to enable the private sector to have a robust record-keeping vehicle for the direct claims on the central bank, which primarily serves as a medium of exchange.

In [ 55 ] construct a model in which banks perform maturity transformation to insure depositors against idiosyncratic liquidity risk. The resulting maturity mismatch can create financial fragility, leading to a bank run by depositors following an adverse shock. The findings suggest that introducing CBDCs leads to fewer maturity transformations. At the same time, the ability of policymakers to monitor the flow of funds in real-time enables them to interfere quicker with the banks that reach fragile conditions.

In [ 46 ] assume a model based on a two-country open economy where only one issues a CBDC. They run a DSGE model to study the effects of potential international spillovers. Their results suggest that the CBDC design is crucial regarding the extent of the shock events. One primary policy recommendation in the paper is applying tight restrictions on foreigners to transact with CBDCs. At the same time, another suggestion is using a flexible interest rate policy on CBDCs. Without optimizing for such policy execution by the issuing economy, the availability of CBDC to non-residents leads to additional volatility in capital flows, exchange rates, and interest rates. CBDC issuance reduces the degree of monetary policy autonomy for the non-issuing economy, making it more than twice more sensitive to fluctuations in inflation and output. The findings suggest a first-mover advantage may be in place if CBDC adoption is inevitable in open economies.

In [ 61 ] discuss particular design choices to be made by policymakers to avoid disrupting the financial system, particularly the disintermediation of private financial institutions. The paper warns against implementing a direct access model, asserting it might lead to disintermediation. In [ 44 ] employs a theoretical framework to show the conditions under which the euro area banking system can avoid similar impediments. The results imply that the increasing role of the European Central Bank (ECB) as the lender of last resort over the past decade may be exacerbated by the introduction of CBDCs designed to prevent disruption to the credit facility and cash. Such a setting may make the ECB politically too involved, a point also made by [ 45 ], who study an account-based CBDC that serves retail and wholesale facilities. In [ 32 ] highlight a similar point regarding the increasing role of central banks in managing financial stability by underscoring that introducing CBDCs may potentially lead to further diminishing the distinction between fiscal and monetary policies.

In [ 12 , 28 , 39 , 45 , 51 ] argue that CBDCs may entirely crowd out bank deposits in weaker economies, underscoring the risk of currency substitution. Inadequate countries with weak monetary and fiscal institutions in the global hierarchy may witness increased currency substitution unless CBDC regulations are designed appropriately to protect the local currencies. Current data on cryptocurrency ownership may be supportive of this proposition. Footnote 13 In [ 74 ] indicates that unregulated global stablecoins such as Libra may exacerbate global wealth imbalances. At the same time, [ 79 ] analyzes the systematic risks of Libra for the euro area and urges a CBDC-backed full-reserve backing license model for such currencies. In [ 35 ] expects private money to coexist with CBDCs and urges central banks to initiate CBDCs as soon as possible to avoid losing political leverage against the increasing currency competition from private currencies. The central claim is that private currencies will be the method of choice for remittances thanks to the lowered transaction costs they offer for exchanging across multiple fiat currencies.

Despite the caveats, there is a more positive view towards specific CBDC designs that may enable fortification state control over domestic payment networks to increase policy robustness against potential currency substitution effects. However, the risk of currency substitution in weaker economies is expected to increase due to this trend. This topic needs a comprehensive discussion on the issue of digital currencies. For example, even though governments may attempt to crack down on private digital payment services, Footnote 14 such currencies are likely to strengthen their use cases as long as a currency is needed for cash-like transactions. Therefore, the purported benefit of CBDCs in preventing dollarization for countries with weak institutional setups may also have little validity unless governments can prevent shadow economies. After all, the source of the demand for stronger currencies results from weak governance, which is outside the scope of macro policy literature.

Alternative approaches

This section reviews the literature on CBDCs that offers an alternative perspective to mainstream research. It covers the scholarly efforts to outline the historical narrative relevant to design approaches for digital money.

In [ 73 ] lays out a more fundamental discussion that enters the realm of the philosophy of money by claiming that digitalization brings forward the immaterial essence of money as a social technology of account. Firmly believing that private digital coins induce pressure on governments to protect public sovereignty, the author expects intense currency competition in immaterial money. The paper argues that deliberate policy choices will be adopted after the experimental phase of private digital currencies to supplant the private rivals in the long run to protect public sovereignty on monetary policy. If individuals/businesses had the option to decide between fully insured central bank deposits and commercial bank deposits, the banking industry would experience a higher risk of disintermediation, as depositors may opt for holding their money in the central bank accounts in times of financial turmoil, as [ 78 ] have proposed.

In [ 40 ] elaborates on the history of financial innovation that began with money in the form of commodities leading to fiduciary money. The paper displays how the past decentralized money precedents tend to consolidate into a public monopoly. In conclusion, the expectation is that the governments will hold onto their monopolistic rights on payment networks. The author questions whether private digital currencies can exist alongside a central bank digital currency, agreeing with [ 80 ] that history suggests competing currencies are nationalized and regulated. Although CBDCs are technically more scalable and historically more favorable to be a winner as the digital form of money, the case comes with significant risks, such as opening the digital money infrastructure to a direct attack vector. Another argument refers to the currency competition envisioned by [ 50 ], which the author also deems unlikely as governments would design their CBDCs to protect their monetary sovereignty.

In [ 27 ] underscores that CBDCs are a global phenomenon and argues that Covid-19 resembles other historically significant shock events such as big wars and the Great Depression. The paper argues that such occasions bring inevitable innovations to the financial system but also acknowledges that central banks must have a comparative advantage over the private sector to achieve innovation, which is challenging. Therefore, it would strengthen the case for CBDCs if public–private cooperation is achieved. Agreeing with [ 40 ] that governments historically have an indispensable role in providing money, the paper speculates that CBDC may bring transparency and innovation to monetary policy, as elaborated in [ 26 ].

In [ 25 ] support the digitalization of public money via the introduction of CBDCs to protect the interest of state instruments, as private digital currencies are increasing at high speed. Through poised regulation, the paper argues that policymakers should strike a balance between private stablecoins and public CBDCs to avoid hampering innovative initiatives in the financial markets. The suggested high-level scheme envisions increasing the stringency of regulations on the increased level of private money adoption while advocating convertibility between the two forms of money.

A critical study missing in this realm is the comparison of CBDCs to previous financial innovations. This review provides a basic comparison between the existing digital financial infrastructure and the improvements expected from the introduction of CBDC with varying design features. However, a more comprehensive study regarding the development of other financial innovations and the development process of central bank monopoly on legal tender could add value as informative literature.

Case studies on CBDCs

The existing case studies are reviewed in this part. The results demonstrate that practical evidence is scarce for the possible implications of leading CBDC design choices. Most of the literature does not exclusively refer to particular design choices.

In [ 81 ] studies the feedback regarding e-Naira’’s adoption, which provides the unique case where a nation with a significant population has released a retail CBDC. In [10, 11] covers the social impacts of the adoption process, showing that the adoption process is dramatically slow. The level of adoption only increased to 6% as of May 2023 despite heavy restrictions on cash usage that led to social problems. On the contrary, cryptocurrency adoption is significantly higher at 50%. Therefore, Nigeria shows that the potential financial inclusion benefits of the e-Naira, as claimed by [ 71 , 72 ], are achieved by cryptocurrencies. Thus, CBDC proponents should decide whether the necessity for adopting CBDCs is to prevent disruption of the existing financial status quo or offer tangible benefits to society. The evidence from Nigeria shows that it is unlikely that CBDC achieves both.

Among the most significant pilot programs, PBoC gradually expands the e-CNY trial. The expansion occurs on a regional basis, where certain cities are selected for inclusion in the pilot. Currently, the pilot adopts an account-based hybrid retail CBDC model. Individuals use a dedicated smartphone wallet application to top-up via cash over the counter or connecting their bank accounts. Despite the strong promotion, the payment system has seen lackluster adoption, as it competes against arguably the most sophisticated digital payment applications in the world with exceptionally high usage rates. In [ 6 ] run a comprehensive review of these Chinese FinTech applications. The advanced form of the Chinese FinTech industry shows the effectiveness of such technologies regarding the improvements in financial inclusion. The authors claim that China may gain further competitive advantage thanks to introducing its CBDC and transforming the international monetary order. The regulations and the current developments on the e-CNY use cases are covered, yet the extent of the available data is slim, as China keeps usage data private.

Based on the feedback loop set through the pilot CBDC cases in the Bahamas, Uruguay, and Sweden, [ 66 ] derive that central bank regulations should foster innovation, allowing a solid private–public partnership to flourish. However, the paper underscores that most experimental work is still in theoretical scope with few pilot programs and even fewer proof of concepts. More time and experimentation are required to obtain better know-how regarding the real-world impact of implementing different CBDC designs.

A recent IMF paper by [ 77 ] focuses on the existing CBDC projects in advanced stages based on their description. These projects belong to the Bahamas, China, Eastern Caribbean, Uruguay, Sweden, and Canada. The scope of the paper is comprehensive as a wide range of topics, such as policy goals, operating models, design features, technical and legal details, and feedback from the operational side of the implementation process, are covered. All of the covered projects use an intermediated operating model. Another observation shows a clear motivation by central banks to avoid disrupting legacy financial systems while upgrading their digital money infrastructure. The authors explain how CBDCs can be designed to avoid competing with bank deposits. Another highlight in the paper concerns the opinion of Sweden's Riksbank that a centralized ledger infrastructure poses the risk of a single point of failure.

An analysis of the design of the Bahamian Sand Dollar, which is the first retail CBDC, highlights the compliance and anti-money laundering requirements despite the tax haven status of the nation [ 84 ]. The Central Bank of Bahamas officially aims to strengthen efforts against anti-money laundering through decreased cash usage. For this reason, the author argues that CBDCs are less advantageous than private cryptocurrencies in reaching adoption. Bahamian Sand Dollars adopt intermediated distribution through banks. The main objective is to prevent bank disintermediation and increase the efficiency and accessibility of the payment network to the domestic market. However, the paper suggests that increasing competition from innovative applications by private cryptocurrencies may undermine the case for a retail CBDC. Overall, the practical feedback generated by the Sand Dollar case is limited.

The conclusion provides a summary of the findings and a discussion on this review’s academic contribution and limitations.

Summary of findings

This literature review aims to identify the underlying determinants of design and implementation-related research on central bank digital currencies. The summary of results shows that there has been a global movement for implementing CBDCs ever since Covid-19 and the proliferation of other digital currencies. The simplest definition is that they are the digital representation of cash, established as a network with a novel technical architecture. The findings are clustered into three distinct approaches: generic research on CBDCs, the mainstream central banking approach, and alternative research approaches. The generic research deals with the standard design features and a comprehensive analysis of benefits, risks, and costs. This section is followed by a survey of mainstream publications on the theoretical macro policy and financial stability topics, trailed by a review of alternative research methods to diversify the scope of opinions. Lastly, the existing case studies are surveyed to identify the practical implications of CBDCs.

Several debates have revolved around the design of central bank digital currencies. Among those, this paper chooses three that are deemed the most crucial. The first debate concerns the distribution model, which can be retail or wholesale. Retail CBDCs are direct central bank liabilities, just like cash, while wholesale CBDCs are distributed through the existing intermediaries in the financial system, such as banks and payment system providers. The next critical design choice is about the operating model, which determines whether the distribution will be solely through intermediaries (indirect), central bank accounts (direct), or a combination of these models. The last significant discussion concerns the access mechanism, which is contingent on the distribution and operating models and deals with the technical grounds of how consumers will interface with the central bank ledger. The options are token-based, account-based, or a combination of both, referred to as the hybrid model. Token-based models are not directly linked to the user's identity, while the account-based model is the opposite. Different combinations of choices have different tradeoffs, and most research on CBDC design choices aims to understand these tradeoffs to find an optimal design based on policy preferences.

Research on potential benefits, risks, and costs associated with CBDCs is widely available for different design characteristics. Besides the functional monetary policy improvements purported by macro policy and financial stability research, most of the expected benefits of introducing CBDCs need more evidence to make a winning case for central bank digital currencies. One scenario that stands out is the landscape of cross-border payments, which can substantially benefit from potential efficiency improvements. Nevertheless, the design discussion for cross-border payments falls heavily within the scope of software architecture to analyze the possible enhancements of CBDC networks over existing payment systems.

Regarding the purported technical and social benefits of introducing CBDCs, such as financial inclusion and improved efficiency in payment systems, there is tangible evidence that the existing financial technologies can already achieve such functions. From private money applications, much evidence shows that security issues can lead to devastating financial losses. Large-scale cyberattacks can shake the confidence in digital public money networks and create social hazards by undermining trust in the financial system.

The majority of the mainstream literature focuses on the design of CBDCs that aims to seek a delicate balance between macro policy considerations and the prevention of disrupting the financial sector. Adopting an account-based retail CBDC is in high demand among central bankers. However, the wholesale CBDC model is often considered a preferable design feature. A primary political objective is to avoid disintermediation of the banks while maintaining the current financial system operationally identical. Therefore, some researchers prefer the intermediated access model due to its conservative nature of placing the banks in an indispensable position and its resemblance to the current functional setting between central banks and financial institutions.

The macro policy considerations focus on expected monetary and fiscal policy benefits. Two studies stand out among the many policy implications that are studied. The first is the introduction of programmable helicopter money, which anticipates a functional gain to make direct payments to households. Such a policy tool may empower state tools to experiment with the demand function of the economy instead of implementing unconventional monetary policies. Another highly anticipated functional gain for central banks is negative nominal interest rates. Some researchers argue that such a feature may bring the added benefits of a higher pass-through speed for the impact of the monetary policy during times of financial turmoil and improve transparency for policy rates.

A radical outcome of introducing negative rates may be the necessity of eliminating cash, which is arguably the most disruptive potential side effect of CBDCs. Multiple authors argue that taking cash out of circulation would be politically too tricky, indicating privacy concerns. However, many believe it will have potential benefits, such as limiting tax evasion, enforcing better AML standards, and preventing the usage of counterfeit cash. However, the expectation of a broader tax and improved AML measures may also be irrelevant since off-the-record economies are not an exclusive by-product of cash usage. Meanwhile, eliminating cash may lead to higher adoption levels for private digital currencies, increasing currency substitution in weaker economies.

Looking at the sheer extent of such implications, multiple authors underscore an increasing obscurity of the separation between fiscal and monetary policies. There are worries that the independence of the central banks may be undermined in the long term, as normalization of such a trend may further engulf central banks in politics.

Alternative literature partly focuses on the practical results from regulatory preparations and adoption challenges, while some scholars study relevant historical arguments for CBDCs. The socioeconomic impact of the digitalization of money, currency competition between private and public money, and direct access to central bank liabilities are vital themes that researchers focus on to bridge past research with the recent rise of digital currencies.

An important finding is that most of the literature disregards public opinion. No evidence supports that CBDCs are demanded by the public, and the communication of the process with the public can be deemed questionable at best, as adoption rates are low for any existing CBDC project. Therefore, research that focuses on public opinion on CBDCs is urgently needed. Notwithstanding, it is possible to speculate that adoption rates may voluntarily increase if inflation remains high in the long term. This review shows that the existing literature could pay more attention to the possibility of persistent high inflation, observing another topic for further theoretical research. To add a more profound perspective to the possibility of a continuous high inflation scenario, a dedicated comparison of the previous financial innovations and the particular policies to establish central bank monopoly on legal tender would provide insight into the upcoming releases of CBDCs and their adoption processes, which may not continue on a smooth transition path.

The practical data from the existing use cases are currently limited. The most significant use case for retail CBDCs is in Nigeria, which displays low adoption rates despite being enforced in society. The outcome of this enforcement has shown results of risking social stability. Meanwhile, meaningful empirical data from such a mass real-world experiment have yet to be retrieved. Several other central banks are ready to take their CBDC networks online. The most notable one is the retail CBDC pilot of China, the e-CNY. Nevertheless, adoption is once again low as Chinese consumers have already adopted very advanced financial technology applications, which have been at their disposal for almost a decade. All in all, as the primary purpose of the R&D efforts shifts from the design stage to the implementation phase, the use cases fail to provide the desired feedback loops for checking the validity of potential benefits and risks associated with different design characteristics.

Academic contribution and limitations

This review endorses a comprehensive and unbiased approach to spot shortcomings and concerns about the fast-growing literature on CBDCs and their design implications.

A significant contribution of this analysis is that it reveals the need for further elaboration of the practical grounds endorsed to justify the urgency for implementing CBDCs at a global level. While doing so, some of the shortcomings within the existing literature are also identified. Ample evidence shows that governments can achieve most of the purported benefits without CBDCs, which are already the reality in certain jurisdictions. Results also display privacy, security, and social risks in implementing retail CBDCs. There needs to be systematic research that considers public opinion on CBDCs. Meanwhile, more research is required to understand the potential scenario where high inflation and negative real interest rates remain sticky in the long term.

Another contribution is the identification of the preferred design choices as the implementation of CBDCs nears at a global scale. The wholesale distribution model is gaining favoritism for the early stages of implementation to avoid disrupting the financial system. The results also show no consensus between wholesale and retail CBDCs, while the latter attracts significant research among central bankers.

Although the movement of CBDC research and development is a global phenomenon, more nuance is needed regarding local considerations. The results exhibit that the literature requires a clear differentiation between local and international implications of implementing CBDCs, and discuss how these implications may differ based on the design choices. The absence of an approach that prioritizes regional implications gives reason to question the scope of CBDC research. After all the research from first-world economies and international institutions, Nigeria became the experimental ground for retail CBDCs. Our findings show that no substantial evidence suggests that Nigerian society is in demand of such a technology. Hence, the conclusive contribution is that the most crucial scope of CBDC research likely lies within the realm of political economy and globalization studies.

As for the limitations, more practical data must be collected from the existing use cases. The difficulty in obtaining sufficient data on cash usage makes it harder to analyze specific claims regarding declining cash usage, which is an often-posed reason for justifying CBDCs. Nonetheless, the most critical limitation is the exclusion of a comparative study on the software architecture of CBDCs. Although such a shift may push the research out of the scope of economic policies, technical discussions are an indispensable part of CBDC research at this point, as specific claims about improved efficiency for cross-border payments require a more comprehensive research scope.

Research data policy and data availability statements

All data generated or analyzed during this study are included in this article (and its supplementary information files).

In [ 15 ] provides a detailed guideline of the role of central bank money in the payment networks.

Data publicly available at https://www.atlanticcouncil.org/cbdctracker/ .

The Digital Currency Institute of the People’s Bank of China, the Hong Kong Monetary Authority, the Bank of Thailand, and the Central Bank of the United Arab Emirates have conducted a six-week trial to conduct a series of real-value transactions among commercial banks. A custom distributed ledger technology-based platform was used to carry out transactions between respective CBDCs [ 23 ].

An exhaustive database for public data breaches is not publicly available. The following are some of the notable recent data exploits that append personally identifiable data: (1) The biometric ID data of the Indian digital ID scheme that even disclosed the banking details of the citizens. (2) Argentina and Turkey national ID database hacks that even include the ID photos of the individuals. (3) Most recently, the personal information of approximately 1 billion Chinese citizens, including names, addresses, national ID numbers, contact information, and criminal records, were hacked.

The cryptocurrency company, Rekt DAO, maintains a comprehensive database of the hacking events that lead to the loss of funds in the cryptocurrency ecosystem. Data publicly available at https://rekt.news/ .

According to the public survey by the Federal Reserve, among more than 2000 commenters, two-thirds have negative opinions about the release of a CBDC in the United States, as “the most common concerns were over financial privacy, financial oppression, and the risk of disintermediating the banking system.”.

Zero Lower Bound is not a deterministic limitation but one that is generally recognized to apply. In practice, central banks have applied negative policy rates. See [ 34 ] for a detailed explanation.

The discussion on negative nominal interest rates precedes CBDCs. In [ 3 ] theorizes a potential solution by applying different time-varying interest rates on electronic and paper money. The peg between paper and electronic money breaks temporarily until desired results are obtained. Electronic money remains the unit of account, and inflation happens relative to paper money. This approach may be susceptible to cash being voluntarily eliminated from circulation depending on the execution of central bank policies during market downturns. CBDC technology is offered as a possible solution for eliminating the systemic risks due to current monetary policy limitations.

World Bank data for Households and NPISHs final consumption expenditure (% of GDP). Data publicly available at https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.CON.PRVT.ZS .

World Bank data for youth unemployment as a percentage of labor force. Data publicly available at https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SL.UEM.1524.ZS .

A specific indicator we have in mind here is the change in income gains of the top 1% against the rest of the population worldwide. The demand continues to weaken as the rich can only spend a certain amount of their wealth. For a detailed guide on the historical trends in the subject, see [ 78 ].

In [ 86 ] claims that the Chinese CBDC should be superior to the existing FinTech systems in all aspects to justify its adoption by public opinion. According to the author, such superiority can be achieved by instituting the programmability function via smart contracts.

Although different surveys may show different results, a market research company, GWI, publishes quarterly data on cryptocurrency ownership by country. There is an evident trend of crypto asset ownership in economies that suffer from high inflation. Details available at https://datareportal.com/reports/digital-2022-july-global-statshot .

In August 2022, the Office of Foreign Assets Control (OFAC) sanctioned the Ethereum mixer service Tornado Cash, which helps transactions on the Ethereum blockchain to be anonymized. The sanction decision was followed by the arrest of a developer of the service in the Netherlands.

Adams, M., Boldrin, L., Ohlhausen, R., & Wagner, E. (2021). An integrated approach for electronic identification and central bank digital currencies. Journal of Payments Strategy & Systems, 15 (3), 287–304.

Google Scholar  

Adrian, T., & Manchini-Griffoli, T. (2019). The rise of digital money (NOTE/19/01; Fintech Notes). International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fintech-notes/Issues/2019/07/12/The-Rise-of-Digital-Money-47097

Agarwal, R., & Kimball, M. (2015). Breaking through the zero lower bound (IMF Working Papers 15/224). International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2016/12/31/Breaking-Through-the-Zero-Lower-Bound-43358

Agur, I., Ari, A., & Dell’Ariccia, G. (2022). Designing central bank digital currencies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 125 , 62–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.05.002

Article   Google Scholar  

Ahnert, T., Assenmacher, K., Hoffman, P., Leonello, A., Monnet, C., & Porcellacchia, D. (2022). The economics of central bank digital currency (Working Paper Series No 2713). European Central Bank.

Allen, F., Gu, X., & Jagtiani, J. (2022). Fintech, cryptocurrencies, and CBDC: Financial structural transformation in China. Journal of International Money and Finance, 124 , 102625. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2022.102625

Allen, S., Čapkun, S., Eyal, I., Fanti, G., Ford, B. A., Grimmelmann, J., Juels, A., Kostiainen, K., Meiklejohn, S., Miller, A., Prasad, E., Wüst, K., & Zhang, F. (2020). Design choices for central bank digital currency: Policy and technical considerations (NBER Working Paper No. 27634). National Bureau Of Economıc Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w27634

Andolfatto, D. (2021). Assessing the impact of central bank digital currency on private banks. The Economic Journal (London), 131 (634), 525–540. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueaa073

Anthony, N. (2022). Update: two thirds of commenters concerned about CBDC . Cato.org. Retrieved August 27, 2022, from https://www.cato.org/blog/update-two-thirds-commenters-concerned-about-cbdc

Anthony, N. (2023). Nigerians’ rejection of their CBDC Is a cautionary tale for other countries | Cato Institute . https://www.cato.org/commentary/nigerians-rejection-their-cbdc-cautionary-tale-other-countries

Anthony, N. (2023). Nigeria’s CBDC was not chosen. It Was Forced | Cato at Liberty Blog . https://www.cato.org/blog/nigerias-cbdc-was-not-chosen-it-was-forced

Arauz, A. (2021). The international hierarchy of money in cross-border payment systems: Developing countries’ regulation for central bank digital currencies and Facebook’s Stablecoin. International Journal of Political Economy, 50 (3), 226–243. https://doi.org/10.1080/08911916.2021.1984728

Auer, R., & Böhme, R. (2021). Central bank digital currency: The quest for minimally invasive technology (BIS Working Papers No. 948). Bank for International Settlements. https://www.bis.org/publ/work948.htm

Auer, R., Haene, P., & Holden, H. (2021). Multi-CBDC arrangements and the future of cross-border payments (BIS Papers No. 115). Bank for International Settlements. https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap115.htm

Bank for International Settlements. (2003). The role of central bank money in the payment systems . (Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems). https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d55.pdf .

Bank for International Settlements. (2018). Central bank digital currencies (CPMI, Markets Committee Papers No. 174). https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d174.pdf

Bank for International Settlements. (2021). Annual economic report . Bank for International Settlements. https://www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/ar2021e.pdf

Bank for International Settlements. (2023). Cross-border exchange of wholesale CBDCs using automated market-makers [Interim report]. Bank for International Settlements.

Barrdear, J., & Kumhof, M. (2022). The macroeconomics of central bank digital currencies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 142 , 104148. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2021.104148

Article   MathSciNet   Google Scholar  

Berentsen, A., & Schar, F. (2018). The case for central bank electronic money and the non-case for central bank cryptocurrencies. Quarterly Research Journals, 100 (2), 97–106. https://doi.org/10.20955/r.2018.97-106

Bindseil, U. (2019). Central bank digital currency: Financial system implications and control. International Journal of Political Economy, 48 (4), 303–335. https://doi.org/10.1080/08911916.2019.1693160

Bindseil, U., & Pantelopoulos, G. (2022). Towards the holy grail of cross-border payments. SSRN Electronic Journal . https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4057995

BIS Innovation Hub. (2022). Project mBridge: Connecting economies through CBDC . https://www.bis.org/publ/othp59.htm

Bjerg, O. (2017). Designing new money—The Policy Trilemma of central bank digital currency. SSRN Electronic Journal . https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2985381

Bolt, W., Lubbersen, V., & Wierts, P. (2022). Getting the balance right: Crypto, stablecoin and central bank digital currency. Journal of Payments Strategy & Systems, 16 (1), 39–50.

Bordo, M. D., & Levin, A. T. (2017). Central bank digital currency and the future of monetary policy (Working Paper No. 23711). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w23711

Bordo, M. D. (2021). Central bank digital currency in historical perspective: Another crossroad in monetary history (Working Paper No. 29171). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29171

Brunnermeier, M. K., James, H., & Landau, J.-P. (2019). The digitalization of money (Working Paper No. 26300). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26300

Buetzer, S. (2022). Advancing the monetary policy toolkit through outright transfers (IMF Working Papers 2022/87; p. 60). International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2022/05/06/Advancing-the-Monetary-Policy-Toolkit-through-Outright-Transfers-517641

Carapella, F., & Flemming, J. (2020). Central bank digital currency: A literature review . https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/central-bank-digital-currency-a-literature-review-20201109.htm

Carney, M. (2019). The growing challenges for monetary policy in the current international monetary and financial system. 23, 377–411

Chen, H., & Siklos, P. L. (2022). Central bank digital currency: A review and some macro-financial implications. Journal of Financial Stability, 60 , 100985. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2022.100985

Chiu, J., Davoodalhosseini, S. M., Hua Jiang, J., & Zhu, Y. (2019). Bank market power and central bank digital currency: Theory and quantitative assessment (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3331135). https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3331135

Cœuré, B., & Brevan, H. (2015). How binding is the zero lower bound? [Speech Transcript] European Central Bank. https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2015/html/sp150519.en.html

Cukierman, A. (2020). Reflections on welfare and political economy aspects of a central bank digital currency. The Manchester School, 88 (S1), 114–125. https://doi.org/10.1111/manc.12333

Cunha, P. R., Melo, P., & Sebastião, H. (2021). From bitcoin to central bank digital currencies: Making sense of the digital money revolution. Future Internet, 13 (7), 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/fi13070165

Davoodalhosseini, S. M. (2022). Central bank digital currency and monetary policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 142 , 104150. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2021.104150

Diamond, D., & Dybvig, P. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. The Journal of Political Economy, 91 (3), 401–419. https://doi.org/10.1086/261155

Edwards, S. (2021). Central bank digital currencies and the emerging markets: The currency substitution challenge. Challenge, 64 (5–6), 413–424. https://doi.org/10.1080/05775132.2021.2004738

Eichengreen, B. (2019). From commodity to fiat and now to crypto: What does history tell us? (Working Paper No. 25426). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25426

Eichengreen, B., & Viswanath-Natraj, G. (2022). Stablecoins and central bank digital currencies: Policy and regulatory challenges. Asian Economic Papers, 21 (1), 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1162/asep_a_00843

Elsayed, A. H., & Nasir, M. A. (2022). Central bank digital currencies: An agenda for future research. Research in International Business and Finance, 62 , 101736. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2022.101736

European Central Bank (2021). The international role of the Euro . https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/ire/html/ecb.ire202106~a058f84c61.en.html .

Fegatelli, P. (2022). A central bank digital currency in a heterogeneous monetary union: Managing the effects on the bank lending channel. Journal of Macroeconomics, 71 , 103392. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2021.103392

Fernández-Villaverde, J., Sanches, D., Schilling, L., & Uhlig, H. (2021). Central bank digital currency: Central banking for all? Review of Economic Dynamics, 41 , 225–242. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.red.2020.12.004

Ferrari Minesso, M., Mehl, A., & Stracca, L. (2022). Central bank digital currency in an open economy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 127 , 54–68. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2022.02.001

Financial Stability Board. (2022). G20 roadmap for enhancing cross-border payments: Consolidated progress report for 2022 (Consolidated Progress Report for 2022). Financial Stability Board. https://www.fsb.org/2022/10/g20-roadmap-for-enhancing-cross-border-payments-consolidated-progress-report-for-2022/

Gkritsi, E. (2021). Shanghai to Test Offshore Yuan Stablecoin on the Conflux Blockchain . Retrieved December 2, 2022, from https://www.coindesk.com/business/2021/09/17/shanghai-to-pilot-offshore-use-of-digital-yuan-on-conflux-blockchain/

Gorodnichenko, Y., Weber, M., & Coibion, O. (2020). How US consumers use their stimulus payments . CEPR. Retrieved September 12, 2022, from https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/how-us-consumers-use-their-stimulus-payments

von Hayek, F. A. (1990). Denationalisation of money: The argument refined ; an analysis of the theory and practice of concurrent currencies (3. ed). Institute of Economic Affairs.

He, D. (2021). Monetary effects on global stablecoins. Cato Journal, 41 (2), 353–366.

Hermawan, D., Lie, D., Sasongko, A., & Yusan, R. (2023). Money velocity, digital currency, and inflation dynamics (MPRA Paper No. 116906). https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/116906/

Infante, S., Kim, K., Orlik, A., Silva, A. F., & Tetlow, R. J. (2022). The macroeconomic ımplications of CBDC: A review of the literature. Finance and Economics Discussion Series . https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2022.076

Ishida, M., Takahashi, W., & Inui, T. (2020). A proposal for an Asian digital common currency . CEPR. https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/proposal-asian-digital-common-currency

Keister, T., & Monnet, C. (2022). Central bank digital currency: Stability and information. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 142 , 104501. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2022.104501

Keister, T., & Sanches, D. (2022). Should central banks ıssue digital currency? The Review of Economic Studies . https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdac017

Khiaonarong, T., & Humphrey, D. (2022). Falling use of cash and demand for retail central bank digital currency (IMF Working Paper WP/22/27). International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2022/02/04/Falling-Use-of-Cash-and-Demand-for-Retail-Central-Bank-Digital-Currency-512766

Komura, N., Unayama, T., & Hattori, T. (2021). Impact of cash transfers on consumption during the COVID-19 pandemic: Evidence from Japanese Special Cash Payments . CEPR. Retrieved September 12, 2022, from https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/impact-cash-transfers-consumption-during-covid-19-pandemic-evidence-japanese-special

Kubota, S., Onishi, K., & Toyama, Y. (2021). Consumption responses to COVID-19 payments: Evidence from a natural experiment and bank account data. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 188 , 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2021.05.006

Kumhof, M., & Noone, C. (2021). Central bank digital currencies-design principles for financial stability. Economic Analysis and Policy, 71 , 553–572. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2021.06.012

Laboure, M., Müller, H.-P., Heinz, G., Singh, S., & Köhling, S. (2021). Cryptocurrencies and CBDC: The route ahead. Global Policy, 12 (5), 663–676. https://doi.org/10.1111/1758-5899.13017

Lee, D. K. C., Yan, L., & Wang, Y. (2021). A global perspective on central bank digital currency. China Economic Journal, 14 (1), 52–66. https://doi.org/10.1080/17538963.2020.1870279

Article   ADS   Google Scholar  

Li, S., & Huang, Y. (2021). The genesis, design and implications of China’s central bank digital currency. China Economic Journal, 14 (1), 67–77. https://doi.org/10.1080/17538963.2020.1870273

Littrell, C. (2022). How to clean up dirty money . Australian Financial Review. Retrieved December 12, 2022, from https://www.afr.com/companies/financial-services/how-to-clean-up-dirty-money-20220811-p5b8yz

Meaning, J., Dyson, B., Barker, J., & Clayton, E. (2021). Broadening narrow money: Monetary policy with a central bank digital currency. International Journal of Central Banking, 17 (2), 1–42.

Morales-Resendiz, R., Ponce, J., Picardo, P., Velasco, A., Chen, B., Sanz, L., Guiborg, G., Segendorff, B., Vasquez, J. L., Arroyo, J., Aguirre, I., Haynes, N., Panton, N., Griffiths, M., Pieterz, C., & Hodge, A. (2021). Implementing a retail CBDC: Lessons learned and key insights. Latin American Journal of Central Banking, 2 (1), 100022. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.latcb.2021.100022

Náñez Alonso, S. L., Echarte Fernández, M. Á., Sanz Bas, D., & Kaczmarek, J. (2020). Reasons fostering or discouraging the implementation of central bank-backed digital currency: A review. Economies, 8 (2), 41. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies8020041

Náñez Alonso, S. L., Jorge-Vazquez, J., & Reier Forradellas, R. F. (2021). Central banks digital currency: detection of optimal countries for the implementation of a CBDC and the implication for payment industry open innovation. Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity, 7 (1), 72. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc7010072

Ozili, P. K. (2022a). Can central bank digital currency ıncrease financial ınclusion? Arguments for and against*. In K. Sood, B. Balusamy, S. Grima, & P. Marano (Eds.), Big data analytics in the ınsurance market (pp. 241–249). Emerald Publishing Limited. https://doi.org/10.1108/978-1-80262-637-720221013

Ozili, P. K. (2022). Central bank digital currency research around the world: A review of literature. Journal of Money Laundering Control, Journal Article. https://doi.org/10.1108/JMLC-11-2021-0126

Ozili, P. K. (2023). Determinants of interest in eNaira and financial inclusion information in Nigeria: Role of Fintech, cryptocurrency and central bank digital currency. Digital Transformation and Society, 2 (2), 202–214. https://doi.org/10.1108/DTS-08-2022-0040

Ozili, P. K. (2023b). Using eNaira CBDC to Solve Economic Problems in Nigeria (SSRN Scholarly Paper 4447036). https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=4447036

Peneder, M. (2022). Digitization and the evolution of money as a social technology of account. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 32 (1), 175–203. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-021-00729-4

Pettis, M. (2019).  Facebook's libra: Does the world need frictionless money?  Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Retrieved August 28, 2022, from https://carnegieendowment.org/chinafinancialmarkets/79396

Romero, J., Wang, Z., & Wong, R. (2021). Should the fed ıssue digital currency? (Economic Brief No. 21–10). Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/economic_brief/2021/eb_21-10#footnote1

Schilling, L., Fernández-Villaverde, J., & Uhlig, H. (2020). Central bank digital currency: When price and bank stability collide (Working Paper No. 28237). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w28237

Soderberg, G., Bechara, M., Bossu, W., Che, N., Davidovic, S., Kiff, J., Lukonga, I., Mancini-Griffoli, T., Sun, T., & Yoshinaga, A. (2022). Behind the scenes of central bank digital currency: Emerging trends, insights, and policy lessons. International Monetary Fund, 2022 (004), 35. https://doi.org/10.5089/9798400201219.063

Stone, C., Trisi, D., Sherman, A., & Beltrán, J. (2020). A guide to statistics on historical trends in ıncome ınequality . Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. Retrieved September 19, 2022, from https://www.cbpp.org/research/poverty-and-inequality/a-guide-to-statistics-on-historical-trends-in-income-inequality

Tercero-Lucas, D. (2020). A global digital currency to rule them all? A monetary-financial view of the Facebook’s LIBRA for the Euro area (Working Paper No. 2020–06). Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona. https://ddd.uab.cat/record/232413

Tobin, J. (1985). Financial innovation and deregulation in perspective. BOJ Economy and Monetary Studies, 3 (2), 19–29.

Tunji, S. (2022, June 7).  How digital divide threatens Enaira's mass adoption . Punch Newspapers. Retrieved August 21, 2022, from https://punchng.com/how-digital-divide-threatens-enairas-mass-adoption/

Wadsworth, A. (2018). The pros and cons of issuing a central bank digital currency. Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin, 81 , 1–21.

Ward, O., & Rochemont, S. (2019). Understanding central bank digital currencies (CBDC). Institute and Faculty of Actuaries , 1–52.

Wenker, K. (2022). Retail central bank digital currencies (CBDC), disintermediation and financial privacy: The case of the bahamian sand dollar. https://doi.org/10.48550/arxiv.2204.01535

Williamson, S. (2022). Central bank digital currency: Welfare and policy implications. Journal of Political Economy, 130 (11), 2829–2861. https://doi.org/10.1086/720457

Yao, Q. (2018). A systematic framework to understand central bank digital currency. Science China Information Sciences, 61 (3), 033101. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11432-017-9294-5

Download references

Open Access funding provided by The University of Tokyo.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Graduate School of Interdisciplinary Information Studies, The University of Tokyo, 7-3-1 Hongo, Bunkyo-Ku, Tokyo, 113-0033, Japan

Huseyin Oguz Genc & Soichiro Takagi

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Huseyin Oguz Genc .

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest.

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

Ethical standards

This article does not contain any studies involving human participants performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Genc, H.O., Takagi, S. A literature review on the design and implementation of central bank digital currencies. IJEPS 18 , 197–225 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-023-00125-9

Download citation

Received : 27 December 2022

Accepted : 05 December 2023

Published : 24 January 2024

Issue Date : February 2024

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s42495-023-00125-9

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Digital currencies
  • Financial technologies
  • Monetary policy
  • Fiscal policy
  • Currency competition

JEL Classification

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

On Digital Currencies

research paper about central bank

For more on Harald Uhlig’s related research:

Benigno, pierpaolo, linda schilling and harald uhlig (2019). global (crypto-)currencies and currency competition . crypto review, 1, 01-03., benigno, pierpaolo, linda schilling and harald uhlig (2022). cryptocurrencies, currency competition and the impossible trinity . journal of international economics, 136., uhlig, harald (2022). a lunatic stablecoin crash . bfi wp 2022-95, becker friedman institute, university of chicago, chicago., uhlig, harald (2023). review article: eswar s. prasad: how the digital revolution is transforming currencies and finance. business economics, 58, 201–204., uhlig, harald and taojun xie (2021). parallel digital currencies and sticky prices . bfi wp 2020-188, becker friedman institute, university of chicago, chicago., for general background on cryptocurrencies:, among a vast literature on the subject, the author recommends the following three articles and one book:, allen, franklin, xian gu and julapa jagtiani (2021). a survey of fintech research and policy discussion. review of corporate finance, 1 259-339., chiu, jonathan, mohammad davoodalhosseini, janet hua jiang, francisco rivadeneyra and yu zhu (2023). central bank digital currencies and banking: literature review and new questions . bank of canada, staff discussion paper 2023-4., kosse, anneke and mattei, ilaria (2023). making headway—results of the 2022 bis survey on central bank digital currencies and crypto . bis papers, no. 136., prasad, eswar s. (2021). the future of money how the digital revolution is transforming currencies and finance. harvard university press, boston, ma., more on this topic.

research paper about central bank

Sticky Discount Rates

research paper about central bank

The High Frequency Effects of Dollar Swap Lines

research paper about central bank

Do Information Frictions and Corruption Perceptions Kill Competition? A Field Experiment on Public Procurement in Uganda

FinancialResearch.gov

Working papers, central bank digital currency: stability and information.

By Todd Keister and Cyril Monnet

Published: July 11, 2022

Share on Facebook Share on Linked In Logo for Twitter

Central Bank Digital Currency: Stability and Information

One often cited concern about central bank digital currency (CBDC) is that it could make runs on banks and other financial intermediaries more common. This working paper identifies two ways a CBDC may enhance rather than weaken financial stability. First, banks do less maturity transformation when depositors have access to CBDC, reducing their exposure to depositor runs. Second, monitoring the flow of funds into CBDC allows policymakers to react more quickly to periods of stress, which lessens the incentive for depositors and other short-term creditors to withdraw assets (Working Paper no. 22-04).

We study how introducing a central bank digital currency (CBDC) would affect the stability of the banking system. We present a model that captures a concern commonly raised in policy discussions: the option to hold CBDC can increase the incentive for depositors to run on weak banks. Our model highlights two countervailing effects. First, banks do less maturity transformation when depositors have access to CBDC, which leaves them less exposed to runs. Second, monitoring the flow of funds into CBDC allows policymakers to identify and resolve weak banks sooner, which also decreases depositors’ incentive to run. Our results suggest that a well-designed CBDC may decrease rather than increase financial fragility.

Keywords: CBDC, digital currency, financial stability, bank runs JEL Classifications: E43, E58, G21

Back to Working Papers

You are now leaving the OFR’s website.

You will be redirected to:

You are now leaving the OFR Website. The website associated with the link you have selected is located on another server and is not subject to Federal information quality, privacy, security, and related guidelines. To remain on the OFR Website, click 'Cancel'. To continue to the other website you selected, click 'Proceed'. The OFR does not endorse this other website, its sponsor, or any of the views, activities, products, or services offered on the website or by any advertiser on the website.

Thank you for visiting www.financialresearch.gov.

  • Public Service That Makes a Difference ®

2022 • 22–21

Research department working papers, looking beyond the fed: do central banks cause information effects.

Several papers present forecasts of improved economic conditions following a surprise monetary policy tightening as evidence of central bank information effects. They theorize that by tightening policy, a central bank conveys a signal about its positive view of the economy. This signal leads to the improved forecasts. Such forecasts contradict standard monetary theory, which holds that policy tightening should cause forecasts to worsen. Other papers argue against the existence of these effects. The research focuses primarily on the Federal Reserve, but this narrow focus limits the number of monetary policy surprises that can be studied. Consequently, choices regarding samples and specifications can lead to large differences in results. In contrast to the existing research, this paper studies the central banks of nine developed countries not including the United States. By doing so, it obtains a measure of precision that is an order of magnitude greater than that of previous studies. Using high-frequency data on interest rates, dates and times of monetary policy meetings, and the changes in forecasts around those meetings, this paper looks for evidence of central bank information effects across and within those nine countries.

social-email-icn

Central Bank Finances and Monetary Policy Conduct

December 12, 2023 Monetary Affairs Department Bank of Japan

  • Full Text [PDF 868KB]

Since the late 1990s, the Bank of Japan, faced with the zero lower bound on interest rates, has implemented various unconventional monetary policy measures. Major overseas central banks have also implemented large-scale asset purchases and other measures since the outbreak of the Global Financial Crisis. Given that such unconventional monetary policies accompanied by large-scale balance sheet expansions have the potential to have a large impact on central banks' finances when monetary policy is tightened, there has been debate on the potential impact on central banks' ability to conduct monetary policy and, by extension, confidence in their currencies.

Central banks earn interest income on the government bonds they purchase and short-term loans they provide, while their liabilities -- current deposits at the central bank (required reserves) and banknotes -- are not subject to interest. This structure usually allows them to generate stable profits (seigniorage).

When the central bank expands its balance sheet under unconventional monetary policy through, for example, the purchase of government bonds, this leads to increases in holdings of government bonds and other assets on the asset side and in current deposits (excess reserves) on the liability side. While the central bank needs to pay interest on excess reserves, since the interest rate on government bonds purchased usually exceeds the interest rate on excess reserves, interest income and other income increase in line with the rise in holdings of government bonds and other assets, so that the central bank's overall profits increase.

On the other hand, during a phase when monetary policy moves toward tightening and the balance sheet shrinks, holdings of government bonds will decrease on the asset side, while excess reserves will decrease on the liability side. When, during this phase, the central bank raises the interest rate on excess reserves, interest expenses will increase, putting downward pressure on its profits. Subsequently, however, interest expenses will decline as excess reserves decrease. Furthermore, since government bond holdings will be successively replaced by higher-yielding government bonds, interest income will increase. Therefore, while the central bank may temporarily make losses during this process, even if this occurs, profits will eventually recover.

The extent to which profits fluctuate during a phase of balance sheet contraction can differ substantially depending on factors such as (1) the size of the balance sheet, (2) the extent to which proceeds from the redemption of government bonds at maturity are reinvested, (3) developments in short-term and long-term interest rates, and (4) developments in banknotes in circulation.

Under a fiat money system, it is important to consider decreases in the central bank's profits and capital from the perspective of whether and how they affect the conduct of monetary policy. In this regard, there are two schools of thought: one is that they adversely affect monetary policy conduct, and the other is that they do not. There are also a variety of positions regarding the theoretical reasons underpinning these views.

Major overseas central banks have recently been tightening monetary policy rapidly and substantially in response to inflation, leading to decreases in their profits and capital. However, in their external communication, they have emphasized that even if they temporarily make losses or have negative equity, this will not impede their ability to conduct monetary policy. Moreover, these central banks have noted that, although their profits are currently decreasing, it is also the case that they increased during the past balance sheet expansion, and that assessments of their large-scale easing policies should focus on the positive effects on the economy overall. Against this backdrop, with a view to avoiding adverse consequences, such as doubts about their ability to conduct monetary policy and a decline in their credibility, these central banks, in recognition of the importance of central bank capital, have maintained their stance to work on restoring their capital over time. Under these circumstances, no particular impediments have arisen in any of the countries or regions in terms of ensuring confidence in their respective currencies through the appropriate conduct of monetary policy.

In light of the above, the relationship between central bank finances and monetary policy conduct can be summarized as follows.

Under a fiat money system, confidence in the currency is not directly ensured by the assets held by the central bank or its financial soundness, but by the appropriate conduct of monetary policy with the aim of achieving price stability. Based on this premise, central banks are generally set up in such a way that they make profits from a somewhat longer-term perspective and, moreover, can supply their own means of payment and settlement. Therefore, even if the central bank temporarily makes losses or has negative equity, this does not impede its ability to conduct monetary policy. That said, this does not mean that the central bank can run up unlimited losses and negative equity. If the central bank's financial risks become a matter of undue attention and give rise to unnecessary confusion over monetary policy, there is a risk that this could lead to a decline in its credibility. Therefore, ensuring the soundness of the central bank's finances is important.

The Bank of Japan deems it appropriate to continue with conducting appropriate policy while also paying attention to its financial soundness.

Please contact below in advance to request permission when reproducing or copying the content of this paper for commercial purposes. Monetary Affairs Department, Bank of Japan Please credit the source when reproducing or copying the content of this paper.

Policy Infrastructure Division Monetary Affairs Department

Tel : +81-3-3279-1111

Check your browser settings and network. This website requires JavaScript for some content and functionality.

Research Discussion Paper – RDP 2024-02 Valuing Safety and Privacy in Retail Central Bank Digital Currency

Zan Fairweather, Denzil Fiebig, Adam Gorajek, Rochelle Guttmann, June Ma and Jack Mulqueeney

  • View the Paper in full
  • View the Paper by sections
  • Download the Paper 1.55 MB
  • Non-technical summary
  • Non-technical summary 146 KB
  • Supplementary information

This paper explores the merits of introducing a retail central bank digital currency (CBDC) in Australia, focusing on the extent to which consumers would value having access to a digital form of money that is even safer and potentially more private than commercial bank deposits. To conduct our exploration we run a discrete choice experiment, which is a technique designed specifically for assessing public valuations of goods without markets. The results suggest that the average consumer attaches no value to the added safety of a CBDC. This is consistent with bank deposits in Australia already being perceived as a safe form of money, and physical cash issued by the Reserve Bank of Australia continuing to be available as an alternative option. Privacy settings of a CBDC, which can take various forms, look more consequential for the CBDC value proposition. We find no clear relationship between safety or privacy valuations and the degree of consumers’ cash use.

https://doi.org/10.47688/rdp2024-02

research paper about central bank

Bank Runs, Fragility, and Regulation

We examine banking regulation in a macroeconomic model of bank runs. We construct a general equilibrium model where banks may default because of fundamental or self-fulfilling runs. With only fundamental defaults, we show that the competitive equilibrium is constrained efficient. However, when banks are vulnerable to runs, banks’ leverage decisions are not ex-ante optimal: individual banks do not internalize that higher leverage makes other banks more vulnerable. The theory calls for introducing minimum capital requirements, even in the absence of bailouts.

The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the Federal Reserve System, or the National Bureau of Economic Research.

MARC RIS BibTeΧ

Download Citation Data

More from NBER

In addition to working papers , the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter , the NBER Digest , the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , the Bulletin on Health , and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship  — as well as online conference reports , video lectures , and interviews .

15th Annual Feldstein Lecture, Mario Draghi, "The Next Flight of the Bumblebee: The Path to Common Fiscal Policy in the Eurozone cover slide

Central bank research hub

The Central Bank Research Hub contains central bank publications which are included in the Research Papers in Economics (RePEc) site.

  • Share this page
  • Sign up to receive email alerts
  • Translations
  • Legal information
  • Terms and conditions
  • Copyright and permissions
  • Privacy notice
  • Cookies notice
  • Email scam warning

Outdated browser

You are using an outdated browser. DNB.nl works best with:

Google Chrome

Central Bank Capital and Shareholder Relationship

Published: 08 April 2024

  • Matteo Bonetti
  • Dirk Broeders
  • Damiaan Chen
  • Daniel Dimitrov

In pursuing its mandate, a central bank assumes financial risks through its mon- etary policy operations. Central bank capital is a critical tool in mitigating these risks. We investigate the concept of central bank capital as a mechanism for risk- sharing with its shareholder. Adopting an option pricing framework, we explore the setting where the central bank commits to distributing dividends when its cap- ital is robust, while the shareholder may be called upon to recapitalize the bank during adverse economic conditions, with negative capital. Our analysis dissects the trade-offs inherent in these options, seeking a mutually beneficial agreement that disincentivizes deviation for either party. This equilibrium is essential for safe- guarding the independence and credibility of the central bank in executing monetary policy effectively.

Keywords: Capital; Central Bank; Contingent Claim Analysis, Risk Management; Shareholder; Stackelberg Games JEL codes G13; G32; E58 Working paper no. 809

809 - Central Bank Capital and Shareholder Relationship

Research highlights:

  • Owned typically by the government, central banks operate within a framework that involves accepting financial risks to implement monetary policy.
  • We investigate the concept of central bank capital as a mechanism for risk-sharing with its shareholder.
  • Adopting an option pricing framework, we explore the setting where the central bank commits to distributing dividends when its capital is robust, while the shareholder may be called upon to recapitalize the bank during adverse economic conditions, with negative
  • We evaluate the trade-offs inherent in the two options, and establish a Stackelberg equilibrium approach to find a mutually beneficial agreement between the central bank and its shareholder.
  • This equilibrium is essential for safeguarding the independence and credibility of the central bank in executing monetary policy effectively.

Discover related articles

  • Working Papers

DNB uses cookies

We use cookies to optimise the user-friendliness of our website.  Read more about the cookies we use and the data they collect in our cookie notice .

To ensure the proper operation of the website, De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) uses functional cookies and analytics cookies, and has taken measures to ensure that these cookies have little or no impact on the privacy of website users.

Some pages include embedded content from external websites. These websites may use proprietary (tracking) cookies. This allows third parties to track visitor statistics, show personalised content and display targeted ads, for example. You can make your choice about allowing these optional cookies both when you first visit the website and when you navigate to a page with embedded content.

Search Results

  • 19 MARCH 2024 · RESEARCH BULLETIN NO. 117

Shocked to the core: a new model to understand euro area inflation

by Marta Bańbura , Elena Bobeica and Catalina Martínez Hernández [ 1 ]

The pandemic's disruption of global supply chains and the spike in natural gas prices following Russia’s invasion of Ukraine were significant drivers of surging inflation. Traditional inflation models often ignore such supply-side shocks, even though they can have a significant and persistent impact on core inflation in the euro area (as measured by rates of change in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices excluding the energy and food components). In response, we propose a new model that takes these and other factors into account, particularly as future inflation dynamics could be shaped by the impact of geopolitical tensions on supply chains and the role of gas in the green transition.

New inflationary drivers come to the fore after the pandemic

Simple models that employ a handful of variables have traditionally proven effective in explaining developments in core inflation. However, the inflationary landscape that unfolded after the COVID-19 pandemic was unprecedented, with price pressures from many different sources hitting the economy at the same time. “Old” culprits, such as oil prices and developments in aggregate demand, played an important role, but “new” types of inflation drivers also gained prominence, most notably those related to gas prices and global supply chain bottlenecks.

Gas price rises used to be largely overlooked as a source of inflation and only came to the fore following the Russian invasion of Ukraine. In the past, in gas supply contracts in Europe prices were indexed to oil prices, and thus typically not considered as inflationary drivers in their own right. However, a gradual shift towards a deregulated gas market in recent years has increased the likelihood of idiosyncratic gas price shocks, with those that occurred following the invasion being a prominent example.

Global supply chain disruptions are another type of inflationary shock that was largely disregarded prior to the pandemic. However, as Carrière-Swallow et al. (2023) argue, shocks to shipping costs have inflationary impacts similar to those of oil and food price shocks. Additionally, Liu and Nguyen (2023) go so far as to say that supply chain pressures accounted for about 60% of the post-pandemic inflation surge in the United States. Therefore, distinguishing global supply chain bottlenecks from more generic supply shocks related to advances in technology might offer useful insights for understanding inflation developments.

A new model for inflation

The multitude of inflationary pressures that arose in the post-pandemic period created the need to expand the information set and employ models incorporating a broader array of variables.

To disentangle the drivers of core inflation, in Bańbura, Bobeica and Martínez Hernández (2023) we employ a Bayesian vector autoregressive model that uses monthly data on 17 variables and identifies eight shocks. On the demand side, these comprise a domestic demand shock and a foreign demand shock, whereas on the supply side we identify shocks related to oil supply, oil-specific demand, gas prices, global supply chain bottlenecks, domestic supply and labour markets.

The identification of “new” shocks comes with the challenge of how to best isolate them from other more standard demand-side and supply-side shocks. For example, the high correlation between oil and gas prices in the past makes it challenging to identify separate shocks in these markets. We assume that positive shocks related to gas price developments increase wholesale gas prices and energy producer prices contemporaneously, and negatively affect economic activity. At the same time, crude oil prices are assumed not to react contemporaneously to gas price shocks, based on previous results in the literature which find that oil prices tend not to be affected by shocks specific to natural gas markets (Rubaszek, Szafranek and Uddin, 2021). Using these restrictions we can distinguish gas price shocks from oil-related shocks.

In order to identify shocks linked to global supply chain bottlenecks, they must be isolated from other influences, particularly those related to developments in energy commodities, which affect shipping costs. Our identification approach relies on restrictions related to the Global Supply Chain Pressure Index (Benigno, di Giovanni, Groen and Noble, 2022) and the euro area Purchasing Managers’ Index for suppliers’ delivery times.

Other shocks are also identified by restricting the contemporaneous reaction of appropriate variables. In order to overcome computational difficulties related to many identifying restrictions, we follow Korobilis (2022), modifying the model to make it fit for a sample including post-pandemic observations. The model’s parameters are estimated with Bayesian techniques, which also helps to avoid overfitting.

What explains the post-pandemic surge in core inflation?

Focusing on the post-pandemic surge, Chart 1 shows the historical decomposition of core inflation.

The drivers of euro area core inflation

Annual percentage changes, in deviations from the mean and from the contribution of initial conditions

research paper about central bank

Sources: Eurostat and authors’ calculations.

Notes: The chart shows the point-wise mean of the posterior distribution of the historical decomposition of core inflation.

Our findings indicate that core inflation in the euro area was largely driven by supply-side shocks during the post-pandemic recovery. We show that global supply chain shocks, gas price shocks and oil price shocks all pushed inflation in the same direction, supporting the narrative that the high inflation episode was due to “bad luck”. In particular, shocks linked to global supply chain pressures and to gas prices made a much larger contribution than in past inflation episodes. Energy-related shocks played a particularly prominent role and accounted for roughly one-quarter of the surge in core inflation from the beginning of 2021 until the peak in early 2023. Gas price shocks comprised about half of that contribution, whereas in the past they typically had little effect on core inflation. Global supply chain shocks made a significant contribution to core inflation, especially from the second half of 2022, although in contrast to e.g. De Santis (2024), we do not find that these shocks made a greater contribution than that of the energy-related supply shocks.

An important finding is that relying on an overly limited set of shocks and variables might exaggerate the importance of certain selected drivers in the post-pandemic period, when many economic series featured simultaneous upward dynamics. As illustrated in Chart 2, the contribution of global supply chain shocks is larger when derived from a smaller model compared with the baseline specification in our paper. The smaller model also overestimates the absolute contribution from these shocks in the low-inflation period.

Global supply chain shocks – contributions to core inflation based on the baseline model and on a smaller model

research paper about central bank

Notes: The chart shows the point-wise mean of the posterior distribution of the contributions to the historical decomposition of core inflation. The smaller model is based on the identification of four shocks using 13 variables while our baseline model uses 17 variables and identifies eight shocks. The bars in yellow (other shocks) show the sum of the contributions of other shocks identified in each model and of the idiosyncratic component.

How central banks look at core inflation

Given the volatility of headline inflation rates, several central banks place special emphasis on core inflation in their communications, as a useful gauge of more domestic and more persistent inflation dynamics. However, core inflation can at times be affected by sizeable supply-side shocks, as happened after the pandemic (see also Lane, 2023).

An important feature of the framework we propose is that we can estimate how core inflation would have developed in the absence of certain shocks, which allows policymakers to “look through” these shocks. A counterfactual measure of core inflation that excludes the effects of energy shocks and global supply chain shocks has been more stable after the pandemic, although it too increased to record levels. The same is true of other popular measures of underlying inflation (see Appendix in Bańbura et al., 2023, and for details on the underlying inflation measures see also Bańbura, Bobeica, Bodnár, Fagandini, Healy and Paredes, 2023).

Conclusions

We argue that a sizeable part of the recent surge in inflation has been driven by supply-side factors, with those related to gas prices and global supply chain bottlenecks playing a prominent role. Such factors are likely to continue to be relevant in explaining future inflation dynamics. Natural gas could be used increasingly in the green transition process, after being classified as a sustainable energy source by the European Commission in 2022. Similarly, disruption along the production chain is likely to reoccur, such as the elevated shipping costs associated with the current tensions in the Red Sea.

For these reasons, inflation models should incorporate shocks to gas prices on top of more traditional oil price shocks. They should also integrate supply chain bottlenecks, in addition to more generic aggregate supply developments. New types of inflation drivers may materialise in the future. An important feature of the model we propose is its adaptability in incorporating new variables and shocks as they become relevant.

Bańbura, M., Bobeica, E., Bodnár, K., Fagandini, B., Healy, P. and Paredes, J. (2023), “ Underlying inflation measures: an analytical guide for the euro area ”, Economic Bulletin , Issue 5, ECB.

Bańbura, M., Bobeica, E. and Martínez Hernández, C. (2023), “ What drives core inflation? The role of supply shocks ”, Working Paper Series, No 2875, ECB.

Benigno, G., di Giovanni, J., Groen, J.J.J. and Noble, A.I. (2022), “The GSCPI: A new barometer of global supply chain pressures”, Staff Reports , No 1017, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May.

Carrière-Swallow, Y., Deb, P., Furceri, D., Jiménez, D., and Ostry, J. D. (2023), “Shipping costs and inflation”,  Journal of International Money and Finance , Vol.130, p.102771, February.

Korobilis, D. (2022), “A new algorithm for structural restrictions in Bayesian vector autoregressions”,  European Economic Review , Vol.148, p.104241, September.

Lane, P.R. (2023), “ Underlying inflation ”, lecture at Trinity College Dublin, 6 March.

Liu, Z. and Nguyen, T. L. (2023), “Global Supply Chain Pressures and US Inflation”, FRBSF Economic Letter , Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, No 2023-14, pp.1-6, June.

Rubaszek, M., Szafranek, K. and Uddin, G. S. (2021), “The dynamics and elasticities on the U.S. natural gas market. A Bayesian Structural VAR analysis”, Energy Economics , Vol. 103, p.105526, November.

De Santis, R. (2024), “ Supply chain disruption and energy supply shocks: impact on euro area output and prices ”, Working Paper Series, No 2884, ECB.

This article was written by Marta Bańbura, Elena Bobeica and Catalina Martínez Hernández (all Directorate General Economics, European Central Bank). The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments of Gareth Budden, Alexandra Buist, Matteo Ciccarelli, Sarah Holton and Alex Popov. It is based on the paper entitled “What drives core inflation? The role of supply shocks” by the same authors, which was published as an ECB Working Paper . The views expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the European Central Bank or the Eurosystem.

Our website uses cookies

We are always working to improve this website for our users. To do this, we use the anonymous data provided by cookies. Learn more about how we use cookies

We have updated our privacy policy

We are always working to improve this website for our users. To do this, we use the anonymous data provided by cookies. See what has changed in our privacy policy

Your cookie preference has expired

COMMENTS

  1. A literature review on the design and implementation of central bank

    Within the last five years, research on Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) has increased with increased momentum. Particular events, such as the growth of private digital currencies, Facebook's attempt to release a stablecoin, the long-term development of Chinese CBDC, and Covid-19, are the leading causes for this growing significant interest. Most recently, the interest converged in ...

  2. Trends in Central Bank Independence: A De-jure Perspective

    Abstract. This paper presents an extensive update to the Central Bank Independence - Extended (CBIE) index, originally developed in Romelli (2022), extending its coverage for 155 countries from 1923 to 2023. The update reveals a continued global trend towards enhancing central bank independence, which holds across countries' income levels and ...

  3. Changing Central Bank Pressures and Inflation

    Changing Central Bank Pressures and Inflation. Hassan Afrouzi, Marina Halac, Kenneth S. Rogoff & Pierre Yared. Working Paper 32308. DOI 10.3386/w32308. Issue Date April 2024. We present a simple long-run aggregate demand and supply framework for evaluating long-run inflation. The framework illustrates how exogenous economic and political ...

  4. Legal Aspects of Central Bank Digital Currency: Central Bank and ...

    This paper analyzes the legal foundations of central bank digital currency (CBDC) under central bank and monetary law. Absent strong legal foundations, the issuance of CBDC poses legal, financial and reputational risks for central banks. While the appropriate design of the legal framework will up to a degree depend on the design features of the CBDC, some general conclusions can be made.

  5. Central bank digital currencies: An agenda for future research

    To this end, this paper aims at highlighting the implications of CBDCs for the macroeconomy and financial systems and identifying emerging trends, and research areas and constructing an agenda for future research. The remainder of the study is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a review of the current state of the literature.

  6. Central Bank Digital Currency and Financial Inclusion

    In this paper, we develop a model incorporating the impact of financial inclusion to study the implications of introducing a retail central bank digital currency (CBDC). CBDCs in developing countries (unlike in advanced countries) have the potential to bank large unbanked populations and boost financial inclusion which can increase overall lending and reduce bank disintermediation risks.

  7. Central bank digital currency research around the World: a review of

    of central banks, about 86% of central banks, were actively researching the potential to issue a. CBDC, 60% of central banks were experimenting with the technology and 14% of central banks. were ...

  8. Central Bank Digital Currency Research Around the World: A ...

    The review shows a general consensus that a central bank digital currency is a liability of the issuing central bank and it has cash-like attributes. The review also presents the motivation and benefits of issuing a central bank digital currency such as the need to improve the conduct of monetary policy, the need to enhance the efficiency of ...

  9. PDF Artificial intelligence in central banking

    Adapting LLMs to central banking terminology can bring further gains, as shown by the central bank language models (CB-LM) project developed at the BIS (Gambacorta et al (2024)). This approach uses thousands of central bank speeches and research papers compiled by the BIS Central Bank Hub to adapt

  10. Impact of Retail CBDC on Digital Payments, and Bank Deposits ...

    Furthermore, an uptick in CBDC usage is associated with a notable decline in bank, cash, and savings deposits, suggesting potential paths to bank disintermediation. This study contributes critical insights into the evolving competition between digital currencies and established financial infrastructures, highlighting the transformative ...

  11. On Digital Currencies

    A Survey of Fintech Research and Policy Discussion. Review of Corporate Finance, 1 259-339. Chiu, Jonathan, Mohammad Davoodalhosseini, Janet Hua Jiang, Francisco Rivadeneyra and Yu Zhu (2023). Central Bank Digital Currencies and Banking: Literature Review and New Questions. Bank of Canada, Staff Discussion Paper 2023-4.

  12. Central Bank Digital Currency: Stability and Information

    One often cited concern about central bank digital currency (CBDC) is that it could make runs on banks and other financial intermediaries more common. This working paper identifies two ways a CBDC may enhance rather than weaken financial stability. First, banks do less maturity transformation when depositors have access to CBDC, reducing their exposure to depositor runs.

  13. PDF Looking Beyond the Fed: Do Central Banks Cause Information Effects?

    The debate on central bank information effects has intensified in recent years, but it has focused primarily on the Federal Reserve. Indeed, this is why central bank information effects are synonymous with the "Fed Information Effect.". However, there is only a limited number of Federal Reserve monetary policy events to study.

  14. PDF Valuing Safety and Privacy in Retail Central Bank Digital Currency

    Retail Central Bank Digital Currency Zan Fairweather, Denzil Fiebig, Adam Gorajek, Rochelle Guttmann, ... Research Discussion Paper RDP 2024-02. Figures in this publication were generated using Mathematica. ISSN 1448-5109 (Online) The Discussion Paper series is intended to make the results of the current economic research within the

  15. (PDF) The Role of Central Banks in Financial Stability ...

    Abstract and Figures. The roles of central banks in the advanced economies have expanded and multiplied since the beginning of the crisis. The conventional monetary policy roles - setting interest ...

  16. (PDF) CENTRAL BANK DIGITAL CURRENCY (CBDC): CHALLENGES ...

    Central bank digital currency (CBDC) is being experimented by more than 60 central banks across the globe. Distributed ledger technology (DLT), which is the foundation for crypto currencies is ...

  17. Looking Beyond the Fed: Do Central Banks Cause Information Effects?

    Full Text Document (pdf) Several papers present forecasts of improved economic conditions following a surprise monetary policy tightening as evidence of central bank information effects. They theorize that by tightening policy, a central bank conveys a signal about its positive view of the economy. This signal leads to the improved forecasts.

  18. (Research Paper) Central Bank Finances and Monetary Policy Conduct

    Since the late 1990s, the Bank of Japan, faced with the zero lower bound on interest rates, has implemented various unconventional monetary policy measures. Major overseas central banks have also implemented large-scale asset purchases and other measures since the outbreak of the Global Financial Crisis. Given that such unconventional monetary ...

  19. Research Discussion Paper

    This paper explores the merits of introducing a retail central bank digital currency (CBDC) in Australia, focusing on the extent to which consumers would value having access to a digital form of money that is even safer and potentially more private than commercial bank deposits.

  20. Bank Runs, Fragility, and Regulation

    Working Paper 32341. DOI 10.3386/w32341. Issue Date April 2024. We examine banking regulation in a macroeconomic model of bank runs. We construct a general equilibrium model where banks may default because of fundamental or self-fulfilling runs. With only fundamental defaults, we show that the competitive equilibrium is constrained efficient.

  21. Central bank research hub

    Central bank research hub. The Central Bank Research Hub contains central bank publications which are included in the Research Papers in Economics (RePEc) site. Published: (dd/mm/yyyy) JEL Code: Filter by: Authors. Authors: Reset.

  22. Research papers

    Research papers. By publishing papers, our researchers create links to the academic community, sparking discussion and debate on topics of relevance to the ECB. This feeds back into the research conducted by our staff, further strengthening the foundations on which future ECB decisions are made.. All our research products have an editorial ...

  23. PDF The Role Of Central Banks In Managing Monetary Policy And It's Effects

    The primary objective of this research paper is to analyse the role of central banks in managing monetary policy and examine its effects on the economy. By delving into this topic, several specific research objectives emerge: 1. To assess the impact of central bank actions on interest rates: This objective aims to investigate how changes

  24. Central Bank Capital and Shareholder Relationship

    809 - Central Bank Capital and Shareholder Relationship. 822KB PDF. Download. Research highlights: Owned typically by the government, central banks operate within a framework that involves accepting financial risks to implement monetary policy. We investigate the concept of central bank capital as a mechanism for risk-sharing with its shareholder.

  25. PDF Working Paper Series

    In this paper, we evaluate the impact of banks' voluntary climate commitments on their lending behavior and on the climate impact of borrowing firms. We organize our empirical analysis around three hypotheses for how bank climate commitments can impact their financed emissions. First, climate-aligned banks can divest from polluting firms and ...

  26. Shocked to the core: a new model to understand ...

    19 MARCH 2024 · RESEARCH BULLETIN NO. 117. Shocked to the core: a new model to understand euro area inflation. by Marta Bańbura, Elena Bobeica and Catalina Martínez Hernández [ 1] The pandemic's disruption of global supply chains and the spike in natural gas prices following Russia's invasion of Ukraine were significant drivers of surging ...

  27. PDF A Study on The Evolution of Central Banks: a Case Study 0f India

    Now, coming to history of the central bank of India i.e RBI . During my research I found out that the establishment of the Reserve Bank of India was a long process along with the process of legislation which began in January 1927 that is 7 years before the central bank was actually established as the presentation took place in March in the year ...

  28. Estimates of New Zealand's nominal neutral interest rate

    Kia ora. I'm Andre, a Senior Economic Analyst here at Te Pūtea Matua - The Reserve Bank of New Zealand. Our research shows that due to high inflation expectations, the Official Cash Rate - or OCR - would need to be about 3.9% to neither tap the brakes nor hit the accelerator on the economy.

  29. Central Bank of Ireland publishes CP158

    On 7 March 2024, the Central Bank published a Consultation Paper on the Consumer Protection Code (CP158). ... News, analysis and research tools covering the regulation and use of data, tech and AI