Featured Topics

alexander-grey-8lnbXtxFGZw-unsplash image

View the  Entrepreneurship Working Group  page.

A picture of a shipping container fully loaded with containers at sea

Econometrics

Microeconomics, macroeconomics, international economics, financial economics, public economics, health, education, and welfare, labor economics, industrial organization, development and growth, environmental and resource economics, regional and urban economics, more from nber.

In addition to working papers , the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter , the NBER Digest , the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , the Bulletin on Health , and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship  — as well as online conference reports , video lectures , and interviews .

2024, 16th Annual Feldstein Lecture, Cecilia E. Rouse," Lessons for Economists from the Pandemic" cover slide

  • A-Z Publications
  • Annual Review of Resource Economics

Annual Review of Resource Economics - Current Issue

  • Navigate this Journal
  • Early Publication

Previous Volumes

  • Editorial Committee

research areas in resource economics

Volume 15, 2023

Preface to the fifteenth volume of the annual review of resource economics.

  • Add to my favorites Favourites

Sir Partha Dasgupta: Meeting the Challenges of Environmental and Development Economics

The Annual Review of Resource Economics presents Professor Sir Partha Dasgupta in conversation with economist Dr. David Zilberman. In the conversation, we follow Sir Partha's life from his childhood in Bangladesh, where his father was a distinguished economist, to his childhood and undergraduate studies in India, his graduate studies in England, and his fascinating academic career, mostly in Cambridge, UK. We discuss Sir Partha's seminal contributions to multiple fields. He was among the founders of modern resource economics and the emerging multidisciplinary field of ecological economics. He also played a fundamental role in establishing the venues and agenda for research on the environment and development, led initiatives to incorporate nature into national accounting, and pioneered analysis of the economics of population growth and the foundation of a just society. We also learn about Sir Partha's family and life, his collaboration and perspective on leading scholars, and his vision for economics, science, and humanity.

Economics of Crop Residue Management

More than five billion metric tons of agricultural residues are produced annually worldwide. Despite having multiple uses and significant potential to augment crop and livestock production, a large share of crop residues is burned, especially in Asian countries. This unsustainable practice causes tremendous air pollution and health hazards while restricting soil nutrient recycling. In this review, we examine the economic rationale for unsustainable residue management. The sustainability of residue utilization is determined by several economic factors, such as local demand for and quantity of residue production, development and dissemination of technologies to absorb excess residue, and market and policy instruments to internalize the social costs of residue burning. The intervention strategy to ensure sustainable residue management depends on public awareness of the private and societal costs of open residue burning.

Food Losses in Agrifood Systems: What We Know

In 2015, the United Nations and the G20 put food loss and food waste on the global agenda. While progress has been made since then, the scale of the problem persists because food loss and food waste are measured together, not separately. The paucity of data also poses a challenge. This article reviews the measurements, causes, and determinants of food loss as well as the interventions to reduce it. The review finds that food loss is considered in isolation, even though it is one of the causes and results of how agrifood systems function. The review calls for improved microdata collection and standardized measurements to separate food loss from food waste. Such efforts would help integrate feedback loops and cascading effects across the value chain with agrifood systems to identify intervention hot spots, trade-offs, and synergies of interventions as well as the effects of food loss reduction on socioeconomic, environmental, and food security goals.

Inferential and Behavioral Implications of Measurement Error in Agricultural Data

An evolving literature evaluates the inferential and behavioral implications of measurement error (ME) in agricultural data. We synthesize findings on the nature and sources of ME and potential remedies. We provide practical guidance for choosing among alternative approaches for detecting, obviating, or correcting for alternative sources of ME, as these have different behavioral and inferential implications. Some ME biases statistical inference and thus may require econometric correction. Other types of ME may affect (and shed light on) farmers’ decision-making processes even if farmers’ responses are objectively incorrect. Where feasible, collecting both self-reported and objectively measured data for the same variable may enrich understanding of policy-relevant agricultural and behavioral phenomena.

Food Fraud: Causes, Consequences, and Deterrence Strategies

Food fraud represents a serious threat to the integrity of the global agri-food marketing system and has received considerable attention by policy makers, academics, and the public at large. This review presents the conditions that enable fraudulent activity in agri-food supply chains (such as asymmetric information, imperfect certification processes, supply chain complexity, and weak monitoring and enforcement systems) and discusses recent efforts to document and deter food fraud and the growing theoretical and empirical literature on the economics of food fraud. The article concludes by identifying some gaps in the literature and provides suggestions for future research.

The Economics of Nutrient Pollution from Agriculture

Nutrient pollution from agricultural sources, coming primarily from fertilization of row crops and manure from livestock operations, affects ecological health in the United States through water and air pollution. We summarize data trends on commercial fertilizer use, manure, cropland, and concentrations of nitrogen and phosphorus in waterways. We present data indicating that fertilizer applications per acre of US cropland exhibit an upward trend, with a strong spatial correlation between agricultural intensification and nutrient contents in waterbodies. While biophysical science has advanced our understanding of how nutrient pollutants affect the functioning of physical ecosystems, economic research has quantified only some of the economic damages related to losses in ecosystem services due to nutrient pollution. Our summary of this work indicates that quantification is incomplete and does not yet provide full characterization of these damages across the country. We summarize key available damage estimates and the limited evidence on cost-effective policy design. We conclude by identifying important yet understudied areas, including a focus on contaminated drinking water sources, health damages from nutrient pollution, and the need for holistic estimates of the costs of the externalities from pollution, where new research efforts will greatly benefit society.

The Market Stability Reserve in the EU Emissions Trading System: A Critical Review

Having experienced low prices for about a decade, the European Union Emissions Trading System has been supplemented with the market stability reserve (MSR) that adjusts the supply of allowances to market outcomes. We critically review the literature assessing the performance of the MSR against several policy objectives. In doing so, we cover both conceptual aspects and quantitative assessments. We conclude by pointing out important policy implications and open issues for further research.

Behavioral Economics and Neuroeconomics of Environmental Values

Identifying mechanisms of real-life human decision-making is central to inform effective, human-centric public policy. Here, we report larger trends and synthesize preliminary lessons from behavioral economic and neuro-economic investigations focusing on environmental values. We review the currently available evidence at different levels of granularity, from insights into how individuals value natural resources (individual level), evidence from work on group externalities, common pool resources, and social norms (social group level) to the study of incentives, policies, and their impact (institutional level). At each level, we identify viable directions for future scientific research and actionable items for policy-makers. Coupled with new technological and methodological advances, we suggest that behavioral economic and neuroeconomic insights may inform an effective strategy to optimize environmental resources. We conclude that the time is ripe for action to enrich policies with scientifically grounded insights, making an impact in the interest of current and future generations.

Environmental Regulation and Labor Demand: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?

Understanding the potential effect of environmental regulation on employment is of broad interest to key stakeholders. Concerns encompass both short- and longer-term effects on workers within the regulated sector, affected communities that already suffer from a lack of employment opportunities, and net employment in the overall economy. We begin our review by presenting a neoclassical microeconomic framework demonstrating how environmental regulations might affect labor demand. We then summarize the main empirical findings from the literature, including sector-specific partial equilibrium estimates and general equilibrium approaches to identifying the employment impacts of regulations. We also briefly describe the literature on how environmental regulations affect labor supply. Finally, we discuss remaining research gaps.

Competition Policy and the Environment

Traditionally, competition law and practice serve to preserve competition, with a focus on the maximization of consumer welfare. This has been criticized as conflicting with society's overarching goal of achieving greater (environmental) sustainability. Consequently, various jurisdictions have recently reformed their laws and guidance allowing them to account for sustainability benefits in the assessment of cooperation between competitors, with potentially considerable implications for how firms can jointly develop and introduce more sustainable technologies and products. This has opened a new research frontier in the long-standing tradition of marrying the theory of industrial organization with the field of environmental and resource economics. The consideration of sustainability benefits in competition analysis also requires both the transfer and adaptation of measurement techniques. We summarize recent developments and sketch potential research opportunities.

The Effects of Temperature on Labor Productivity

This article reviews recent economic studies on the causal effects of temperature on labor productivity. The negative effects of extreme temperatures are widespread, and the magnitudes of the impact differ across social and economic factors. In addition to physical outputs, extreme temperatures also impair mental productivity, including cognition and learning. In utero exposure to extreme temperatures has profound effects on human development. Although the literature has detected various adaptation strategies, the conclusions are mixed. We discuss some limitations of existing studies and propose several directions for future research.

A Review of the Financial Sector Impacts of Risks Associated with Climate Change

This article reviews the literature on the financial sector impacts of natural disasters and physical climate change risks, covering banking, insurance, stock markets, bond markets, and international financial flows. Most studies have applied statistical approaches to historical data from developed countries to identify these impacts, while some have also used theoretical and computational modeling to assess future risks under climate change scenarios. The findings show that natural disasters and climate change risks generally lower insurer profitability and risk-sharing capacity, bank stability and credit supply, returns and stability of stock and bond markets, foreign direct investment inflows, and international lending. Factors such as income levels, rigorous financial regulations, capital abundance, market diversification, and adaptation strategies mitigate the negative effects. Natural disasters increase remittance inflows and financial assistance to low- and middle-income countries. We recommend future research on forward-looking computational modeling to assess the future financial sector impacts of climate change, while accounting for adaptation actions and their drivers. Future research should also consider hazard correlations and the interactions between financial industries and regions to more comprehensively assess the economic effects of natural disasters in general and for vulnerable countries in particular.

Do Different Estimation Methods Lead to Implausible Differences in the Size of Nonobserved or Shadow Economies? A Preliminary Answer

This review evaluates three micro and three macro estimation approaches to determine whether unrealistic differences exist in estimating the size of nonobserved/shadow economies. While some macro-MIMIC estimates are higher than estimates using the statistical discrepancy approach, when adjusting for double-counting, MIMIC approaches provide similar results. Macro approaches usually cover not only typical shadow economy activities, but also voluntary work, do-it-yourself activities, and classical crime activities; by nature, macro approaches will lead to higher and more accurate estimates than micro approaches. However, if certain adjustments are made, the estimated size of the shadow economy using the MIMIC approach comes close to the size of the shadow economy indicated by micro survey approaches. Hence, claims that macro approaches are unrealistically high and rely on unrealistic assumptions must be reconsidered.

Food Insecurity in the United States: Measurement, Economic Modeling, and Food Assistance Effectiveness

We first discuss the genesis and development of the Food Security Module in the United States. We then present a conceptual model of food insecurity, drawing on consumer choice theory. The model shows how food insecurity exhibits a quality–quantity trade-off and has linkages to policy levers. Next, we present new stylized facts pertaining to food consumption for those who report food insecurity versus those who do not. Adults residing in food-insecure households consume lower-quality diets across the entire distribution of diet quality and experience more volatility in caloric intake. Males younger than 20 years in food-insecure households exhibit no differences in diet quality but consume fewer calories, while the opposite is true for younger females. We review the literature pertaining to the effects of federal food assistance programs on food insecurity. The Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program tends to reduce household food insecurity, while having little to no effect on nutritional quality. Federal programs pertaining to children (i.e., the school food programs and the Special Supplemental Nutrition Program for Women, Infants, and Children) tend to reduce food insecurity while also increasing the nutritional quality of children's diet.

Social Protection and Rural Transformation in Africa

This article develops a conceptual framework on pathways through which noncontributory social protection can support resilient and inclusive agricultural growth in rural Africa. It draws insights from a review of rigorous empirical evidence on the impacts of cash transfers and multifaceted cash plus programs on a range of relevant productive outcomes, including accumulation of productive assets, inputs and farm management practices, off-farm labor and nonfarm enterprises, and farm production and income. This review demonstrates an emerging consensus in the literature: that access to social protection programs contributes positively to increasing the productive asset holdings of rural people, increasing the use of improved inputs and farm practices, and shifting away from casual wage labor arrangements. Moreover, there is limited evidence on heterogeneous effects across different baseline characteristics (income, sex, and labor-constrained households, among others). Finally, the article highlights how social protection programs should be considered an integral part of broader rural and agricultural development strategies in order to achieve a more productive, resilient, and equitable rural transformation in Africa.

Economics of Ecosystem Restoration

Restoration of degraded ecosystems is essential for having a stable climate, reducing weather extremes and disease burden, producing enough food to feed growing populations, and generally keeping the world livable. However, we are currently rapidly degrading ecosystems worldwide, thus destroying the very basis of life. There is a major gap between what investments are needed to restore degraded ecosystems and prevent further degradation and what is actually being invested. In addition, most governments are still learning how to design and implement ecosystem restoration policies that are effective and efficient. Ecosystem restoration should be among our main scientific endeavors. This review fills a critical gap in the existing literature by providing a theory-informed understanding of the findings emerging from this highly policy-relevant strand of resource economics. The article also suggests key areas for future research.

Agroecology for a Sustainable Agriculture and Food System: From Local Solutions to Large-Scale Adoption

Agroecology is often considered as the ultimate and most comprehensive solution to the many challenges of the agricultural and food system, also referred to as the agri-food system. This review investigates to what extent agroecology can become the mainstream model for transforming agriculture toward more sustainable and resilient agri-food systems within the given economic and political context. We find that enhancing agroecology will require a fully integrated multiscale systems approach from farm to region to globe. The approach must consider relevant processes and relationships, actors and stakeholders as well as drivers, sustainability indicators, and the respective assessment methods across all scales. Giving specific attention to drivers related to economy, technology, and policy we point out that agroecology needs to be economically viable for farmers and other food system actors. In particular, new and emerging technologies related to digitalization and breeding should be given more consideration in agroecological transformation. We stress the need for an analytical and operational framework and adequate multiscale policy design and suggest six areas of needed attention to support the large-scale adoption of agroecology.

The Role and Use of Mathematical Programming in Agricultural, Natural Resource, and Climate Change Analysis

Climate change undeniably impacts agriculture and natural resources, enterprises and markets. For informed decision making, there is a need for information on climate change adaptation possibilities and mitigation alternatives. Mathematical programming has been used to address the economic aspects of such questions and allows analysis as climate change moves the environment into previously unobserved conditions. It allows us to model spatial and dynamic features of the issue and analyze heretofore unobserved adaptation and mitigation possibilities. This review provides an overview of and references for modeling techniques, conceptual issues, and major assumptions involved with using mathematical programming as a climate change economic analyzing engine, along with a brief comparison with other methods. We also review a number of studies applying mathematical programming to examine climate change impacts, adaptation, and mitigation issues in the agricultural and natural resources arena. Finally, we present a very brief discussion on research needs.

A New Wave of Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Taxes: Are They Meeting Policy Goals and Can We Do Better?

Little progress has been made in reducing deaths from chronic noncommunicable diseases associated with being overweight or obese worldwide, prompting the World Health Organization and others to recommend the implementation of taxes on sugar-sweetened beverages (SSBs). In response, SSB taxes have been widely implemented over the last decade, and a burgeoning literature aims at understanding their effects. We assess the state of knowledge regarding the impacts of SSB taxes and provide context for the results reported to date based on the recent consumer behavior literature and incentives of supply-chain intermediaries in modern food markets. Evidence suggests only a portion of a tax on distributors or manufacturers is passed forward to consumers, inducing only mild and highly variable impacts on SSB purchases. We argue that the literature provides no consistent evidence that SSB taxes have incentivized increased purchases of healthier beverages and caused overall SSB consumption to decrease. Finally, we consider the efficacy of SSB taxes, alone or in combination with other policies, as part of jurisdictions’ policy goals, including promoting healthier diets, generating revenue, and improving equity.

14 Ahead of Print Articles

Volume 15 (2023)

Volume 14 (2022), volume 13 (2021), volume 12 (2020), volume 11 (2019), volume 10 (2018), volume 9 (2017), volume 8 (2016), volume 7 (2015), volume 6 (2014), volume 5 (2013), volume 4 (2012), volume 3 (2011), volume 2 (2010), volume 1 (2009).

New Content Item

Environmental and Resource Economics

The Official Journal of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists

The primary concern of Environmental & Resource Economics is the application of economic theory and methods to environmental issues and problems that require detailed analysis in order to improve management strategies. The contemporary environmental debate is in a constant state of flux, with new or relatively unexplored topics continually emerging. The Journal provides a forum for the further exploration of causes, consequences and policy responses linked to these topics, across a range of spatial and temporal scales up to the global dimension. Areas of particular interest include evaluation and development of instruments of environmental policy; cost-benefit and cost effectiveness analysis; sectoral environmental policy impact analysis; modeling and simulation; institutional arrangements; resource pricing and the valuation of environmental goods; and indicators of environmental quality. The contents are chosen for their relevance to the process of policy formulation and application.

  • Ian J. Bateman,
  • Ana Espinola-Arredondo,
  • Alistair Munro

Societies and partnerships

New Content Item

Latest issue

Volume 87, Issue 8

Special Issue: Ecosystems and human health

Latest articles

Border carbon adjustments and leakage in the presence of public pollution abatement activities.

  • Nikos Tsakiris
  • Nikolaos Vlassis

Can the Superposition of Green Policies Improve the Investment Efficiency of High-Polluting Firms Even More?

research areas in resource economics

The Effects of Growing Groups and Scarcity on the Use of a Common Pool Resource – a Lab-in-the-Field Experiment with Lake Victoria Fishers

  • Astrid Dannenberg
  • Charlotte Klatt

research areas in resource economics

Prospects for Markets for Internationally Transferred Mitigation Outcomes under the Paris Agreement

All inclusive climate policy in a growing economy: the role of human health.

  • Lucas Bretschger
  • Evgenij Komarov

Journal updates

Supporting the sustainable developmental goals.

New Content Item

Special Issue by invitation only: Green Resources for the Energy Transition

This Special Issue is a compendium of articles with important value added to the discussion of the opportunities and challenges for the achievement of a green and sustainable economy, characterized by its inclusiveness and resilience.

Call for Papers: Special Issue on Environmental Economics and Economic Dynamics

The NED (Nonlinear Economic Dynamics) conference provides a platform for an interdisciplinary exchange of ideas between researchers in economics and mathematics to understand economic dynamics from several viewpoints and for the study of a vast range of economic problems. Over the years, increasing attention has been devoted to the interaction between economic and environmental dynamics. This issue has recently been prioritised by several academic scholars, politicians and governments all around the world pinpointing well-known concerns about the environment (e.g., climate change, demographic-economic-environmental transitions, etc.). The main goal of this special issue is to integrate environmental economics and economic dynamics (both at the micro and macro levels) possibly also considering the related public policies.

European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists

The European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (EAERE) is an international scientific association which aims are:- to contribute to the development and application of environmental and resource economics as a science in Europe;- to encourage and improve communication between teachers, researchers and students in environmental and resource economics in different European countries;- to develop and encourage the cooperation between university level teaching institutions and research institutions in Europe.Founded in 1990, EAERE has over 1000 members in 60 countries, from Europe and beyond, from academic institutions, the public sector, and the private industry. Interests span from traditional economics, agricultural economics, forestry, and natural resource economics.

Journal information

  • ABS Academic Journal Quality Guide
  • Astrophysics Data System (ADS)
  • Australian Business Deans Council (ABDC) Journal Quality List
  • CAB Abstracts
  • Current Contents/Social & Behavioral Sciences
  • EI Compendex
  • Engineering Village – GEOBASE
  • Google Scholar
  • INIS Atomindex
  • Japanese Science and Technology Agency (JST)
  • OCLC WorldCat Discovery Service
  • Research Papers in Economics (RePEc)
  • Social Science Citation Index
  • TD Net Discovery Service
  • UGC-CARE List (India)

Rights and permissions

Editorial policies

© Springer Nature B.V.

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

research areas in resource economics

Research Trends in Environmental and Resource Economics: Insights from four Decades of JEEM

  • KCG Journal Articles
  • Publications

Authors: Roland Kube, Andreas Löschel, Henrik Mertens and Till Requate (Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2018, Vol. 92, 433-464)

This paper provides a contemporary analysis of how research issues have developed in the Journal of Environmental Economics and Management ( JEEM ) over the four decades of its existence. We have classified the articles in the journal along five dimensions: content, methods, environmental media, the regional dimension of studies, and cross-cutting issues. While up to about 10 years ago, non-m arket valuation and cost-benefit analysis, natural resource economics, and environmental policy instruments represented the lion’s share of articles published in the journal, more recently we observe a significant shift towards a more diversified array of research areas, with climate change and energy issues finding their way into the journal. In addition, increasing methodological plurality becomes apparent, reflected in a significant shift away from economic theory and towards empirical approaches. We also analyze key distinctions between the major environmental economics journals. Finally, we analyze JEEM’s external influence on leading general economics (A+) journals. We find that A+ citations are positively correlated with a focus on climate change economics, market-based environmental policies and policy comparisons, the use of econometric and statistical methods or exp erimental approaches, and negatively correlated with a focus on water pollution and other pollutants such as pesticides.

Keywords: environmental economics research issues, research trends, environmental economics journals, citation impacts

DOI: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2018.08.001

Involved Team members

  • Prof. Dr. Till Requate

Other Projects

research areas in resource economics

JavaScript disabled

You have to enable JavaScript in your browser's settings in order to use the eReader.

Or try downloading the content offline

Did you know?

Reader environment loaded

Loading publication (154.6 KB)

Large documents might take a while

Jump to navigation

Search form

Agricultural and Resource Economics | Home

  • Prospective Graduate
  • Prospective Undergraduate

research_overview_marquee.jpg

women looking at laptop computer

Faculty in the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics conduct research, data analysis, and forecast modeling related to local and global agricultural industries, natural resource economics, trade, and development economics in countries around the world. As part of the University of Arizona’s Land Grant Mission, we also specialize in Arizona agriculture and natural resource economics with Cooperative Extension faculty focused on understanding Arizona’s economic drivers and trends that impact local communities.

Agricultural Economics Research

Agriculture has always been an important contributor to Arizona’s economy. Understanding the impact of this sector on the state, nation, and developing countries is vital to establishing policies that that support prosperity for our local community and communities around the world. Our research in agricultural economics and agribusiness brings to light key data and information needed for sound economic decisions.

Resource Economics Research

Faculty focused on resource economics research the supply, demand, and allocation of the Earth's natural resources. We apply state-of-the-art quantitative and econometric tools to understand and identify challenges we may face in the future and opportunities for economic interventions such as estimating water price elasticities of residential water demand.

Development Economics Research

Our researchers in development economics examine international trade policy, natural resource management, and global food security and policy in underdeveloped countries and emerging nations. Faculty members in this area seek to understand how variables in income, access to credit, labor supply, and resources impact communities in relation to educational access, gender equality, and other factors related to standards of living.

Research Focus Areas

Agricultural economics & agribusiness.

We focus on developing efficient management strategies for adapting to changes in water scarcity, farm regulation, and climate change.

Agricultural Economics Policy

We conduct applied research and analysis of major policies important to U.S. and Arizona agriculture as well as issues related to energy and international trade.

Applied Econometrics

We are engaged in developing and applying new econometric techniques to the issues of causal identification and out-of-sample forecasting.

Development Economics

We work in Africa, Asia, and Latin America on topics related to agriculture, natural resource management, food security, risk, and problems of agency.

Natural Resource & Environmental Economics

We seek to better understand the challenges of managing water, energy, and the environmental in the context of a changing climate.

Cardon Working Papers Series

In honor of former professor and dean of the College of Agriculture, Bartley P. Cardon, the Cardon Working Paper Series highlights recent research in agricultural and applied economics. 

Graduate Theses

Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics graduate students complete theses in a variety of research areas. 

Environmental, Resource and Energy Economics

research areas in resource economics

Hunt Allcott

research areas in resource economics

Lawrence H. Goulder

research areas in resource economics

Allan Hsiao

Rosamond L. Naylor

Rosamond L. Naylor

David a. starrett.

research areas in resource economics

Frank Wolak

Natural Resource and Environmental Economics Research

Department of agricultural and resource economics.

Many faculty and students in  Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics  are engaged in cutting-edge research in the fields of environmental and natural resource economics, with an emphasis on non-market valuation, water economics, natural resource economics and policy, recreation economics, public lands management, and invasive species. CSU’s location along the Colorado Front Range provides exceptional opportunities for applied local and regional analysis of environmental and resource issues, and we partner closely with the U.S. Forest Service and other state and federal agencies to develop research projects that help inform decision-makers and shape public policy. Among the sub-disciplines:

Non-market Evaluation

Dr. John Loomis  is a leading scholar in the field and has completed a wide range of valuation projects on such diverse resources as rivers, recreational fisheries, public lands, endangered species, water quality, and forest fires. Dr. Craig Bond,  Dr. Dana Hoag , and co-author Dr. Gorm Kipperberg have researched farmers’ preferences for private and public good attributes of irrigation systems. Other faculty in DARE have applied these techniques to attributes related to food products, such as the valuation of organic beef or nutritionally-enhanced foods.

Water Economics

The work of Professors  Christopher Goemans  and  James Pritchett  provide examples of ongoing water resource related research within the department. Dr. Goemans is currently conducting research relating to municipal water demand management and understanding the potential effects of climate change on municipal water systems. In collaboration with the City of Parker, Dr. Pritchett is part of a project aimed at developing alternative irrigation strategies for farmers faced with limited water supplies.

Natural Resource Economics

Much of Dr. Craig Bond’s research is in this field, with a focus on numerical dynamic modeling and management implications. More specifically, he has written articles on sustainable management, the relationship between governance and pollution, and agricultural abatement costs, and is currently working on projects involving forest management and invasive species and adaptive resource management, as well as several valuation studies. Dr. Paul Huszar’s research in the natural resources/environmental economics area entails both domestic and international projects. Most recently, his domestic work has been concerned with the non-consumptive use of agricultural water. Prior to that his work concerned off-site costs of wind erosion. Internationally, his recent work has been on the sustainable use of grassland and forest resources in the Gran Chaco of Argentina and an evaluation of the environment impacts of the development of river navigation in Brazil and Argentina. Prior to this work, he investigated the sustainability of upland soil conservation programs in the uplands of Java, Indonesia.

Environmental Economics

Dr. John Loomis  is a leading scholar in the environmental economics. His body of work in this field includes over 160 peer-reviewed publications on benefits of protecting natural environments. Dr. Craig Bond, Dr. Dana Hoag, and Dr. Gorm Kipperbeg have worked on farmers’ preferences for private and public good attributes of irrigation systems.

Resource Policy

Resource policy examines the interface of agriculture and the environment. Several faculty in the DARE have looked at water use and conservation, organic foods, wildlife (e.g. prairie dogs, elk, deer), ecosystem function, sustainability, public and private land use, water pollution from agriculture, conservation easements and agricultural preservation.

Recreation and Tourism Economics

Tourism and recreation are among the fastest growing and most important economic activities across the globe. They are of particular importance to a state with abundant and relatively unique natural features such as Colorado. Our national parks and protected areas, our fish and wildlife, our wild rivers and streams and, of course, our mountains attract millions of visitors per year and increase the well being of Coloradoans in at least two ways: (1) direct enjoyment citizens of Colorado receive from visiting these areas; (2) employment, income and taxes generated by non-resident visitors to Colorado. Several DARE faculty research areas such as agritoursim.

Public Lands Management

Dr. John Loomis  has conducted research on how visitors to Rocky Mountain National Park respond to changes in natural resources influenced by climate change. He has researched how visitation to Grand Teton National Park and the National Elk Refuge change with different numbers of elk and bison. A major focus of his research is how much visitors and the general public would pay to reduce risk of catastrophic wildfires on public lands through use of prescribed burning and mechanical fuel reduction.  Dr. Andrew Seidl  has conducted research on how visitors to the Monarch Butterfly Sanctuary in Michoacan, Mexico, Glaciers National Park in Argentine Patagonia and cruise tourists visiting marine and terrestrial parks and archeological sites in Central America and the Caribbean respond to changes in the quality and costs of tourist services. A major focus of his research surrounds the distribution of the financial returns of tourism development and the incentives for natural resource stewardship in developing countries and communities.

Our websites may use cookies to personalize and enhance your experience. By continuing without changing your cookie settings, you agree to this collection. For more information, please see our University Websites Privacy Notice .

College of Agriculture, Health and Natural Resources

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics

Erik katovich.

Assistant Professor

Current Appointment

PhD in Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2022

MS in Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2020

BS in Economics, University of Minnesota-Twin Cities, 2015

Research Areas

Environmental and Resource Economics

Development Economics

Political Economy

ARE 2250. Energy Economics: Sustainable Transitions (available Fall 2025)

ARE 6203. Economics Methodology: Praxis and Practice

ARE 5495/6695. Global Energy Transitions

G o o g l e Scholar

research areas in resource economics

Email
File Curriculum Vitae
Mailing Address1376 Storrs Road, W.B. Young 303A Storrs, Connecticut 06269-4021
Link

research areas in resource economics

Book series

Studies in Energy, Resource and Environmental Economics

About this book series.

  • Georg Erdmann,
  • Anne Neumann,
  • Andreas Loeschel

Book titles in this series

The geopolitics of hydrogen.

Volume 1: European Strategies in Global Perspective

  • Rainer Quitzow
  • Yana Zabanova
  • Open Access
  • Copyright: 2024

Available Renditions

research areas in resource economics

Circular Business Models in the Manufacturing Industry

Insights from Small Open Economies

  • Lina Dagilienė
  • Jurgita Bruneckienė
  • Viktorija Varaniūtė
  • Justina Banionienė
  • Copyright: 2023

research areas in resource economics

Smart Cities

Social and Environmental Challenges and Opportunities for Local Authorities

  • Fateh Belaïd
  • Anvita Arora

research areas in resource economics

Vulnerable Households in the Energy Transition

Energy Poverty, Demographics and Policies

  • Rossella Bardazzi
  • Maria Grazia Pazienza

research areas in resource economics

Publish with us

Jump to navigation

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics | University of California, Berkeley:

  • Letter from the Chair

Agricultural and Resource Policy

  • Development Economics
  • Environmental and Energy Economics
  • Department History
  • Ciriacy-Wantrup Postdoctoral Fellowships
  • Support ARE
  • Room Reservations
  • Graduate Program
  • Undergraduate Program
  • Current Candidates
  • Post Doctoral Fellows on the Market
  • Past Placements
  • Equity+Inclusion

irrigation in a field

Research Areas

At the department's inception, farm management was the main area of emphasis in ARE. Over time, our department has diversified and modernized, and our research in the area of agricultural and resource economics has expanded well beyond this initial focus. Some aspects of the department's current program include the following:

  • Farmer decision-making
  • Risk and insurance
  • Storage and inventory management
  • Technology adoption and diffusion
  • Water and soil conservation
  • Pest management
  • Biofuels and renewable energy

ARE faculty and graduate students have made important contributions over the years to general economic theory regarding decision making under uncertainty, technology choice, environmental health risks, storage and commodity price dynamics and other areas, and have applied these new theories to problems of agriculture in California and around the world. Departmental researchers have also made important contributions to the literature on water use, resource conservation and pest management.

Farming in developed countries is going through processes of a transition. Its share of GNP is declining, yet it has become part of a large agribusiness sector that includes input suppliers, major distributors, and manufacturers of value-added food and fiber products. ARE conducts research on many problems relevant to the agribusiness complex including

  • Industrial organization
  • Production contracts
  • Biotechnology and intellectual property
  • Agricultural finance

Much of our work in agricultural economics and agribusiness is closely linked to policy questions. Many departmental faculty and alumni have long and distinguished records of government service, and are at the forefront of policy development and evaluation. Our graduate courses in agricultural and resource policy incorporate techniques of policy evaluation drawn from public finance, welfare economics, and applied econometrics.

Ellen Bruno, PhD's picture

Ellen Bruno

Alain De Janvry's picture

Alain de Janvry

Marco Gonzalez-Navarro's picture

Marco Gonzalez-Navarro

Daniel Gordon's picture

Michael Hanemann

Alexandra Hill's picture

Alexandra Hill

Rania Lachhab's picture

Rania Lachhab

Aprajit Mahajan's picture

Aprajit Mahajan

Jeffrey Perloff's picture

Jeffrey Perloff

Gordon Rausser's picture

Gordon Rausser

David Roland-Holst's picture

David Roland-Holst

David L Sunding's picture

David Sunding

Sofia Villas-Boas's picture

Sofia Berto Villas-Boas

Brian WRIGHT's picture

Brian Wright

David ZILBERMAN's picture

David Zilberman

Graphic representation of skyline in bright colors

Best-Performing Cities 2024: Focus on Sustainable Growth and Resilience

Photo of Maggie Switek

Key Takeaways

• Austin–Round Rock, TX, gains one position, becoming the best-performing large city for the first time since 2013. 

• After its remarkable three-year run as the top-ranked large metropolitan area, Provo–Orem, UT, forfeits the number one position due to declines in its labor market.

• Most of this year’s top-ranking metropolitan areas are in landlocked states, with only one top-tier city (Charleston–North Charleston, SC) along a coastline. 

• Top-ranking small cities display a particular geographic concentration, with four of the seven top-tier small metros (Idaho Falls, Coeur d’Alene, Twin Falls, and Pocatello) located in Idaho.

The Best-Performing Cities (BPC) 2024 rankings evaluate the performance of 403 metropolitan areas across the US based on 13 indicators that cover labor market conditions, high-tech impact, and access to economic opportunities.

As the post-pandemic economy reaches a new status quo, metropolitan areas remain at the heart of the nation’s growth. Almost 6 million new jobs were created across US metro areas during 2022. Simultaneously, interest rates on mortgages more than doubled, adding to the attractiveness of locations offering jobs with higher wages and lower costs of living. 

Along with affordability, sustainability of growth is a matter of increased importance when ranking the Best-Performing Cities. The COVID-19 pandemic, coupled with recent weather-related events such as storms and floods, has focused attention on cities’ resilience to natural and economic disasters. Recognizing the importance of sustainable and equitable growth, this year’s BPC ranking incorporates a community resilience metric that summarizes the ability of a metropolitan area to recover from various kinds of disasters. Also incorporated into this year’s index is a new measure of income inequality that accounts for the social sustainability of growth (with cities with lower inequality ranked higher).

The Best-Performing Cities (BPC) 2024 ranking provides a comprehensive assessment of cities’ performance.

2024 Best-Performing Cities Rankings Highlights

Woman with light brown hair smiling, wearing a pink blouse against a neutral background

Maggie Switek

Smiling light-skinned, male-presenting individual with short dark hair wearing a dark shirt.

Brock Smith

Related content.

research areas in resource economics

Best-Performing Cities 2023: Thriving in a Changing Economic Landscape

Decorative

Global Opportunity Index 2024: Attracting Foreign Investment

Photo of Leilani Jimenez

Best-Performing Cities 2018: Where America’s Jobs Are Created

research areas in resource economics

Best-Performing Cities and Microbusiness Activity: Exploring Policy Implications of Online Economies

Best-performing cities 2017: where america’s jobs are created and sustained.

research areas in resource economics

Best-Performing Cities 2022

research areas in resource economics

State Technology and Science Index 2022

Wide, multicolored lines on a dark blue background

Mexico's Competitiveness as a Strategic Trade Partner Interactive Map

research areas in resource economics

Best-Performing Cities China 2021: The Nation’s Most Successful Economies

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings

Preview improvements coming to the PMC website in October 2024. Learn More or Try it out now .

  • Advanced Search
  • Journal List
  • Springer Nature - PMC COVID-19 Collection

Logo of phenaturepg

Twenty Key Challenges in Environmental and Resource Economics

Lucas bretschger.

1 CER-ETH Centre of Economic Research at ETH Zurich, ZUE F7, 8092 Zurich, Switzerland

Karen Pittel

2 ifo Center for Energy, Climate and Resources, ifo Institute and LMU Munich, Munich, Germany

Economic and ecological systems are closely interlinked at a global and a regional level, offering a broad variety of important research topics in environmental and resource economics. The successful identification of key challenges for current and future research supports development of novel theories, empirical applications, and appropriate policy designs. It allows establishing a future-oriented research agenda whose ultimate goal is an efficient, equitable, and sustainable use of natural resources. Based on a normative foundation, the paper aims to identify fundamental topics, current trends, and major research gaps to motivate further development of academic work in the field.

Introduction

Research frontier.

The research agenda in environmental and resource economics has always been very broad and dynamic, reflecting the ways our economies interact with the natural environment. While in classical economics of the eighteenth century the factor land played a dominant role, the effects of pollution externalities, resource scarcities, ecosystem services, and sustainability became important in subsequent time periods. These issues have triggered different waves of research with very prominent results, specifically on optimal policies in the presence of externalities (Pigou 1920 ), optimal extraction of non-renewable resources (Hotelling 1931 ), optimal capital accumulation in the presence of resource scarcities (Dasgupta and Heal 1974 ), and sustainable development (Hartwick 1977 ; Pearce et al. 1994 ). Of course, the list of topics has already been very diverse in the past but has increasingly become so with recent global environmental problems challenging the functioning of a world economy which is growing at a high rate and heavily relies on an international division of labour and trade.

In the past, new research challenges emerged and manifested in different ways: Some topical fields became increasingly relevant due to new technological developments, new ecological or societal challenges or new political agendas. Others arose in fields that were already well researched but rose in importance. Not all challenges were of a topical nature. In some fields, we found our methodological tool-kit not equipped to deal with new problems or in need of extension to find new (and better) answers to old questions. At the same time, it has become increasingly clear that we have to reach out to other disciplines to meet new and often immense challenges. In environmental economics it is key to seek a good balance between disciplinary excellence, interdisciplinary collaboration, and political impact.

Environmental and resource economics is a dynamic field, in which new key topics emerge frequently. So, while the topical and methodological challenges that the paper identifies will be important for some time to come, they will and should also be subject to further development over the next years and decades. The paper aims to identify and address the variety of new complex problems generated by humans when they exploit natural resources and the environment. We specifically identify Twenty Challenges that we feel will be important for environmental and resource economists to address. We are aware that such a list will never be unanimously agreed upon and we do not even lay claim on the list being complete; the next section provides a background to the compilation of the list. Nevertheless, we feel it to be important to (at best) point researchers in directions important to work in in the future or (at least) to launch a new—controversial but productive—discussion on the development of our field. In any case, the paper should support the profession to operate at the research frontier generating novel theories, empirical designs, and workable policies. But, before we turn to the Twenty Challenges , we aim to motivate the framing of research in our field—past, present and future.

Identification of Research Challenges

To provide a normative foundation for our research agenda we characterize our underlying assumptions and generalized views on the nature of research in the field. This set of basic assumptions motivates the criteria of importance, activeness, and distinction of the selected topics as well as our choices with respect to design, methodology and research methods. Identifying the relevant issues, i.e. the mere choice of what to study in environmental economics imposes specific values on the subjects. In our view, the guiding principle in the normative framework is that environmental economics differs from general economics by its ontology, i.e. the system of belief that reflects the interpretation of what constitutes an important fact. It is a deep and serious concern about the state of the natural environment that drives the economic analysis of ecological processes. Nature is not simply part of the economic system but a different system with its own very complex regularities and dynamics; ecosystem values are not reducible to market exchange values. The task to integrate the ecological and economic systems to a holistic framework in an appropriate manner and to derive valid guidelines for the economy under the restrictions imposed by the environment lies at the heart of our research. Central parts of the ontology are the valuation of ecosystems, the increasing scarcities in natural resources and sinks, the effects of environmental externalities, the long-term orientation of planning, an important role of uncertainty, and the existence of irreversible processes. The anthropocentric view and the use of utilitarianism do not imply that individuals are purely self-centered and narrowly selfish. It highlights the indistinguishable role of human decision making for the future of the planet and aims at decision making that cares for efficiency, equity, and posterity. Based on a broad utilitarian setup, growth is not valued in terms of material consumption but in terms of wellbeing, which includes elements like social preferences, work-life balance, appreciation of nature etc. Posterity reflects our care for future generations, whose welfare should not be harmed by the activities of current generations. Fundamental changes of the economy e.g. the phase-out of fossil fuels, includes policy-induced decrease of activities, a role for technology, substitutability in production and consumption, a decoupling from natural resource use, and internalizing cost to correct market failures. Substantive transitions are very difficult to implement, as important lock-in mechanisms such as habit persistence, built infrastructure, and supporting policies such as subsidies stabilize current practices. To achieve a change of mindset in politics to achieve a transition to a green economy is a difficult task. A fundamental systems change, as discussed by many these days, is undoubtedly much more complex to accomplish; its impacts are uncertain and may delay the necessary steps which are important to rapidly improve the state of our ecosystems.

We acknowledge that one can always challenge an ontological position because it reflects ethical principles. In our research agenda there is no external reality, independent of what we may think or understand it to be. We reduce economic and ecological complexity through our personal system of belief to design our preferred map, which by definition is not the territory. In his survey of ecological research issues for the economists, Ehrlich ( 2008 ) refers to his ”own mental meta-analysis” to motivate his choices and to alert us to the importance of research on big issues like the meaning of life, mortality, and death. At the same time, he acknowledges that the emergence of pervasive new environmental problems, such as climate change and biodiversity loss, requires to flexibly adjust research programs to societal demand. Adjustments of the agenda may also be supply driven, when new methods allow for more effective engagement with important issues like risk and uncertainty or assessment of empirical regularities with superior estimation methods.

Forming a Research Agenda

Environmental economics is closely linked to general economics in its epistemology, i.e. the validity, scope and methods of acquiring knowledge by using models, distinguishing between positive and normative models, and testing hypotheses with empirical methods and experiments. An important cornerstone for economic research has always been the analysis of economic efficiency. Since the early days of environmental economics research, this has also held for our field whether it concerned the efficiency in the use of natural resources or the design of policies. Although research in our field has become much more interdisciplinary and policy-oriented, this still constitutes common ground. It is still a prime duty of the economist to point at the potentially vast allocative inefficiencies of the use of natural resources in pure market economies. Efficiency is a necessary condition for optimal states of the economic-ecological system and the foundation for policies maximizing social welfare.

The pursuit of optimality has to be complemented by a requirement to take care of equity and posterity enabling sustainability of development. In this long-run perspective, economics has to highlight the substitution effect as a powerful mechanism establishing consistency between humanity and its natural environment. Substitution comes in many guises, e.g. as substitution between clean and dirty production, renewable and exhaustible resources, extractive and conservationist attitude, pollution intensive and extensive consumption, etc. This dynamic analysis is crucial in many respects. It has recently been included at all levels of research in the fields. The same holds for the issue of risk and uncertainty, a pervasive topic when dealing with the environment.

In many cases, there has been a significant discrepancy between the theoretical derivation of social optima in academia and the attempts to foster their implementation under realistic policy conditions. As a consequence, policies dealing with environmental issues have been of very different quality and effectiveness. The reduction of acid rains, the protection of the ozone layer, and cutbacks of particulate matter emissions in many world regions were among the prominent successes. Global warming, extraction of rare earth elements, and loss of biodiversity are not yet addressed in a comprehensive manner. Political resistance against the protection of nature often refers to the economic costs of policies, including the concerns of growth reduction, employment loss, and adverse effect on income distribution. The lack of success in many policy areas has led to reformulation and extension of the research agenda. In the future, research should focus more on strengthening the links between theory and policy.

Our selection of the Twenty Challenges is also based on the potential of research in these areas to contribute and leverage social welfare and sustainable development. We specifically look for areas that are either inherently new to the research agenda in environmental and resource economics or in which research stagnates. We present the challenges in a specific order and like to highlight the links between them before we enter into the details. The aim of net zero carbon emission by the mid of the century dominates current policy debates and unites basically all important elements of our discipline; it thus constitutes a good starting point. Decarbonization necessarily involves a deep understanding of systems dynamics and of risk and resilience, which are presented next. An important and not sufficiently addressed research issue is the emergence of disruptive development during a substantive transition, the next challenge for our research. Extending the scope, we then address human and government behaviour. In the context of environmental policy, the popular and sometimes underrated request of an equitable use of the environment has emerged as a dominant topic, a next issue for further research. As natural capital involves many more elements than the climate, biodiversity and general ecosystem services are included in the sequence. Broadening the scope to the big problems of human behaviour with natural resources we then turn to political conflicts, population development and conflicting land use. Shifting the focus on induced movements of the labour force we go on by dealing with environmental migration and urbanization. These affect welfare of the individuals in a major way, like health and the epidemiological environment as a next research challenge. In terms of the reorganization of the transition to a green economy we highlight the central role of finance and the implementation of new measures in the dominant energy sector. The final three research challenges are motivated by advances in the methodology. Big data and machine learning offer new perspectives in sustainability research, refined methods and increasing experience improve our simulation models and structural assessment modelling, which forms the last three challenges of our list.

Links to Current Research

In order to put our agenda into a broader perspective and to concretize the selected challenges, we believe it is important to show the relationship between our research agenda and the priorities in current literature and policy debates. We have considered three main links. First, we conducted a quantitative and qualitative literature review and analyzed current research as presented at international conferences (World Conference of Environmental and Resource Economics in 2018, the SURED conference in 2018, Meetings of the American, European, and Asian Associations of Environmental and Resource Economics in 2019). The aim of this analysis was to see where our profession moves and which of the currently hotly debated topics offers a high potential for future research. Second, we took the discussions in interdisciplinary research fora into consideration to identify further fields that are of high importance for future resource use, sustainable development and environmental outcomes but have so far not been adequately addressed from an economics perspective. Information on this research was gained through interdisciplinary research initiatives (for example The Belmont Forum, Future Earth and National Research Funding Activities). Involvement in interdisciplinary and globally oriented research councils provided further access to the discussions in other disciplines. Third, we draw conclusions from current policies and news as well as our involvement in the policy arena. The authors are involved in a number of institutionalized policy-oriented activities on the regional, national and international level (Regional Climate Councils, National Climate Policy Platforms as well as the UN climate negotiations).

The paper relates to similar contributions in recent literature. Based on citation data Auffhammer ( 2009 ) identifies important topics and scholars and provides a brief historical overview of the discipline from exhaustible and renewable resources to sustainability, pollution control, development, international trade, climate change, international agreements, and non-market valuation. Polyakov et al. ( 2018 ) analyze authorship patterns using text analysis for classification of articles in Environmental and Resource Economics. Based on 1630 articles published in the Journal from 1991 to 2015 they document the importance of applied and policy-oriented content in the field. They identify non-market valuation, recreation and amenity, and conservation, as popular topics and growing when measured by both number of articles and citations. Costanza et al. ( 2016 ) investigate the most influential publications of Ecological Economics in terms of citation counts both within the journal itself and elsewhere. Important topics turn out to be social aspects of environmental economics and policy, valuation of environmental policy, governance, technical change, happiness and poverty, and ecosystem services. A contemporary analysis of how research issues have developed in the Journal of Environmental Economics and Management in the time of its existence is provided by Kubea et al. ( 2018 ). These authors show that the sample of topics has broadened from the core issues of non-market valuation, cost-benefit analysis, natural resource economics, and environmental policy instruments to a more diversified array of research areas, with climate change and energy issues finding their way into the journal. In addition, increasing methodological plurality becomes apparent. They conclude that energy, development, and health are on the rise and that natural resources, instrument choice, and non-market valuation will endure; multidisciplinary work will be increasingly important. An excellent survey on research in the central field of sustainable development is provided in Polasky et al. ( 2019 ), which explicitly shows where the collaboration between economists and the other disciplines is currently insufficient and how it should be intensified in the future.

Regarding the literature that we connect our Twenty Challenges to, we naturally face the problem that some challenges have so far not been addressed adequately in the (economics) literature. In these cases we also reference papers from other disciplines. We, however, also take basic literature and recent research in environmental and resource economics into account. As we often deal with emerging topics, we cite some of this work even when not yet published. In other cases, where future research can build on or learn from past research, we also go back in time and reference older papers. Ultimately, neither our list of challenges nor the literature we base our analysis on will be satisfying to everybody. Our selection cannot be comprehensive and does not claim to be. But the specific task to identify future-oriented topics ultimately lasts on a subjective individual assessment of the authors. Nevertheless, hopefully it imparts impulses for future research in the different subfields of environmental and resource economics.

Twenty Challenges

The ordering of the following challenges should not be understood to perfectly reflect their individual importance (beyond what we explained in the previous sections). Also, many of the fields discussed are inherently related, creating some unavoidable overlap. We feel that efforts to bring the challenges into some complete ’natural order’ are not only doomed to fail but also would not do them justice as they relate to very different areas and can/should not be weighed against each other. Also, attempting to show their interrelations would result in a 20-by-20 matrix that would not provide more clarity.

  • Deep decarbonization and climate neutrality To limit global warming to a maximum of 1.5 degrees Celsius, a state of net zero greenhouse gas emissions—i.e. climate neutrality—should be reached by the mid of the century (IPCC 2018 ). The directly following and unprecedented challenge is to decarbonize the global economy in very a narrow time window (Hainsch et al. 2018 ). This holds especially as the threshold for 1.5 degrees is expected to be passed around 2040 (IPCC 2018 ). Countries must increase their NDC ambitions of the Paris Agreement more than fivefold to achieve the 1.5 degree goal (UN - United Nations 2019 ). The time window for necessary decisions is closing fast. Infrastructure that is installed today often has a life span that reaches until and beyond 2050. Decisions on investments today therefore affect the ability to reach climate targets not only in 2030 but also 2050 and beyond. And while the necessity of reaching net zero emissions by mid century is reflected by, e.g., the European Commission’ Green Deal, much uncertainty remains regarding its implementation. This holds to an even larger extent with respect to other countries and regions. The fundamental challenge is to better understand economically viable deep decarbonization paths and then to implement incentives for input substitution, technology development, and structural change. More specifically, the vision of these policies has to be long-term and reach beyond phasing out coal and increasing energy efficiency. However, despite recent research efforts in climate economics, many issues around decarbonization, negative emissions and economic development are still controversial or insufficiently understood by economists. Specifically, industry applications for which alternative technologies are not available yet as well as agricultural emissions will have to be addressed. Also, the later greenhouse gas emissions start to fall, the faster their decline will have to ultimately be in order not to overshoot temperature targets (Agliardi and Xepapadeas 2018 ), leading to an increased need for negative emissions. However, potential trade-offs and synergies in the use of land for negative emission technologies, food production and biodiversity are still underresearched. Identifying technologies today that are the most promising in the very long run is subject to high uncertainty. Yet, while investing too early might be costly, delaying investment might cost even more or might lead to a weakening of future climate targets (Gerlagh and Michielsen 2015 ). Also, transition processes may involve strong scale effects implying nonlinear development of abatement cost. Once certain thresholds are reached, lower abatement cost or even disruptive development completely altering the production process could emerge in a later phase of decarbonization. Given the dramatic increase needed in mitigation efforts to reach the 1.5 or even 2 degree target, more attention also has to be devoted to the question of adaptation. Until today, the focus of research as well as policy has been primarily on mitigation rather than adaptation, partially because of expected substitution effects between mitigation and adaptation and partially because adaptation was taken to be automatic (Fankhauser 2017 ). However, as Fankhauser lays out “knowledge gaps, behavioral barriers, and market failures that hold back effective adaptation and require policy intervention”. All of these topics present a wide scope for substantial further research.
  • Dynamics of the economic-ecological system Depletion of exhaustible resources, harvesting of renewable resources, recycling of raw materials, and accumulation of pollution stocks require basic societal decisions which are of an inherently dynamic nature. Whether the world society will be able to enjoy constant or increasing living standards under such dynamic natural constraints depends on another dynamic process, which is the accumulation of man-made capital. To derive the precise laws of motion in all the stock variables is challenging because general solutions of dynamic systems with several states are usually hard to obtain. An adequate procedure to obtain closed-form solutions may be to link several stocks in a reasonable way, e.g. when simultaneously dealing with resource, pollution, and capital stocks (Peretto 2017 ; Bretschger 2017b ). The specific challenge is then to find the best possible economic justification to motivate the links. One may also focus on a few stocks which are considered the main drivers of economic development and sustainable growth on a global scale (Marin and Vona 2019 ; Borissov et al. 2019 ). When resorting to numerical simulation methods it is a main challenge to provide basic economic results which are sufficiently robust and supported by ample economic intuition. Social-ecological systems are increasingly understood as complex adaptive systems. Essential features of these systems - such as nonlinear feedbacks, strategic interactions, individual and spatial heterogeneity, and varying time scales—pose another set of substantial challenges for modeling in a dynamic framework. A main challenge is the characterization and selection of dynamic paths with multiple equilibria and the overall tractablility of the models, given the diversity of interlinkages and nonlinear relationships. The complexity of economic-ecological systems lead to a main challenge for designing effective policies is taking account of network effects, strategic interaction, sectoral change, path dependencies, varying time lags, and nonlinear feedbacks have to be considered as well as different regional and temporal scales, interdependencies between ecosystems, institutional restrictions and distributional implications (see, e.g., Engel et al. 2008 ; Levin et al. 2013 ; Vatn 2010 ). Optimal policies should also acknowledge the balance between the preservation of the ecology and the development of the economy especially for countries growing out of poverty. Setting a price for ecosystem services and natural capital via policy is important for preventing innovation incentives from being skewed against maintaining natural capital and ecosystem services.
  • Risk, uncertainty, and resilience The vast majority of contributions in environmental economics use models with a purely deterministic structure. However, large negative environmental events require a completely different framework, which poses specific challenges for modelling. Heatwaves, floods, droughts, and hurricanes are shocks that are very uncertain, arriving at irregular times and with varying intensity. Also, risk and uncertainty about socio-economic impacts and technological development affect the optimal design of policies (see, e.g., Jensen and Traeger 2014 ). Moreover, uncertainty changes the political economy of climate policy and, finally, regulatory and policy uncertainty might create obstacles to reach climate targets through, for example, distortions of investment decisions (Pommeret and Schubert 2018 ; Bretschger and Soretz 2018 ). Stern ( 2016 ) argued forcefully that climate economics research needs to better integrate risk and uncertainty. Bigger disasters or so-called ”tipping points” such as the melting of the Greenland ice sheet, the collapse of Atlantic thermohaline circulation, and the dieback of Amazon rainforest involve an even higher level of uncertainty (Lenton and Ciscar 2013 ) with implications for optimal policy design and capital accumulation (Van der Ploeg and de Zeeuw 2018 ). Understanding the implications of tipping points is further complicated as the different tipping points are not independent of each other (Cai et al. 2016 ). The Economy and the Earth system both form non-deterministic systems; combining the two in an overarching framework and adding institutions for decision making multiplies the degree of complexity for adequate modelling and methods (Athanassoglou and Xepapadeas 2012 ). It is thus a main challenge for further research to provide analytic foundations and policy rules for rational societal decision-making under the conditions of risk and uncertainty up to deep uncertainty (Brock and Xepapadeas 1903 ; Baumgärtner and Engler 2018 ). Future work on policy design under deep uncertainty can build on a wide range of literature ranging from the assessment of the precautionary principle in this context to the fundamental contributions by Hansen and Sargent ( 2001 ) and Klibanoff et al. ( 2005 ) as well as on more recent analyses in the context of environmental and resource economics, e.g. Manoussi et al. ( 2018 ). An important challenge of the environmental discipline is to provide a framework for the global economy providing the conditions for resilience against major shocks and negative environmental events (Bretschger and Vinogradova 2018 ). With deep uncertainty one has to generate rules for deep resilience. Including uncertainty is especially important when environmental events do not occur constantly but cause the crossing of tipping points involving large and sudden shifts. Economic modeling needs to increasingly incorporate tipping points and the value of resilience in theory and to generate and use data supporting the empirical validity. The combination of uncertainty and potential irreversible outcomes (e.g., species extinction) is another big challenge for research.
  • Disruptive development and path dependencies Substantial and sometimes disruptive changes in behavioral patterns, economic structure and technologies will be required if net zero GHG emissions and the UN sustainable development goals are to be reached. On the bright side, development may exhibit favorable disruptions. Consumers’ preferences and political pressure coupled with new technology achievements may alter certain sectors in a short period of time. Similar to the communication industry which has completely changed, transportation and heat generation could and mst probably will undergo fundamental changes in the near future. The research challenge here is to provide adequate models predicting and adequately analyzing such important transitions and to highlight resisting forces at the same time. In fact, the change of trajectories in development is often hampered by technological, economic and behavioral lock-ins, resulting in path dependencies and inertia. In such situations, history influences current development through, for example, past investment in R&D, the size of established markets, increasing returns or habits acquired (Aghion et al. 2016 ; Barnes et al. 2004 ; Arthur 1989 ). Behavioral path dependencies affect acceptance and adoption of new technologies, hinder social innovation and might render policies aimed at marginal changes ineffective. They can thus postpone the transition to a low-carbon economy, harm efforts in biodiversity conservation and prolong unsustainable resource use patterns and lifestyles, even if they are welfare enhancing in the long-run (e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2012 ; Kalkuhl et al. 2012 ). Inertia and lock-ins may also be policy driven with, for example, political or economics elites trying to block change (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006 ) or clean energy support schemes fostering new technology lock-ins. Whether disruption or a lock-in emerges depends, for example, on expectations determining the steady state of an economy (Bretschger and Schaefer 2017 ). This requires nonlinearities e.g. in capital return, generating overlap regions in which the growth path is indeterminate and could be either driven by history or by expectations. The challenge is to add more substantial research into system dynamics and the political economy of change, to gain a better understanding of the different mechanisms responsible for inertia and disruptive change. So far, the role of path dependencies has often been neglected in empirical as well as theoretical analyses (Calel and Dechezlepretre 2016 ). Also, understanding the triggers or tipping points for disruptive change can help to identify policies that have a big environmental impact with moderate costs in terms of environmental policy.
  • Behavioral environmental economics Traditionally, economics focuses predominantly on the supply side when analyzing potentials and challenges for environmental policies. Preferences of individuals are mostly assumed to be given with economic analysis confining itself to studying the effects of changing incentives and altering constraints. The change and development of preferences over time plays only a comparative minor role for economic research. Also, the follow-up question whether policies should be allowed to tamper with preferences is rarely discussed with nudging being one big exception to this rule (e.g. Strassheim and Beck 2019 ). While the traditional, supply-side oriented analysis has provided powerful results in positive analysis, it proves to be limited in a field which inherently includes normative conclusions like environmental economics. The path toward sustainable development requires behavioral changes and political actions changing our relationship to the environment. Ultimately, environmental policies have to be decided by the same people overusing the environment in the absence of a policy. In situations where outcomes are inefficient because individuals and political actors follow their own self-interest and ignore external costs and benefits of their actions, it is clearly not sufficient for economists to advocate the implementation of environmental policies. It is crucial to understand under what conditions preferences change and agents support green policies (Casari and Luini 2009 ). So, the challenge to economic research is to better understand the evolution of green attitudes, the emergence of preferences for a clean environment, and expectations in the case of multiple equilibria (Cerda Planas 2018 ). The formation and development of preferences is also not independent from cultural, regional and community aspects. Research that ignores heterogeneity among actors or the role of social and group dynamics and only relies on the traditional, isolated analysis of individual preferences is likely to lead to an incomplete understanding of preference dynamics. As the example of discounting shows, the social context has an impact on myopic attitudes and the motivation to undertake sacrifices for a cleaner future (Galor and Özak 2016 ). Also, attention to behavioral details, that economists might find rather uninteresting from a research perspective, might influence effectiveness of policies tremendously (Duflo 2017 ). Especially with the natural environment, the choice and guise of policy instruments should take these mechanisms into account.
  • Institutional analysis of environmental policy Virtually every contribution to the environmental and resource economics literature culminates in one or several policy conclusions. However, these results are often received with skepticism from industry and public. Therefore, a continuing key challenge for our profession is a thorough understanding of environmental policy institutions, processes and decision-making; this task has become even more important given the enormous scale and global nature of future policies. Research in this area has, however, the advantage of already looking back on a long tradition (see e.g. the body of work by Daniel Bromley, e.g. Bromley 1989 ). Well-designed institutions support and create incentives to drive development toward a welfare-improving state. Absent, weak, inefficient, or even corrupt governments and institutions are detrimental to successful environmental policy (Pellegrini and Gerlagh 2008 ; Dasgupta and De Cian 2016 ) or might lead to detrimental effects of resource wealth (see Badeeb et al. 2017 for an overview of the related literature). To effectively increase social welfare by, for example, conservation of ecological services, one has to design policies in a way that allow implementation under realistic policy conditions (Rodrik 2008 ). Pure reference to the construct of a social planner is not sufficient. For increasing efficiency in problem solving, the ex-post evaluation of policies has to be expanded and improved. Policy evaluation should not only analyze if regulatory objectives have been reached but also which side-effects arise (OECD 2017 ). Moreover, the comparison with alternative measures and a continuous international exchange of best practices have to be supported by science. A proactive environmental policy analysis should furthermore include studying vested interests, lobbying, political power, policy communication, and voting behavior. Especially insights from behavioral economics may add to our understanding of a proper design of environmental institutions. On the international level, the adequate institutional design for global environmental policy still poses great challenges. Beyond traditional research fields like international environmental agreements in specific areas like climate change, the multi-dimensionality of the sustainable development goals (SDGs) and potential trade-offs between different goals need to be explored further. This holds especially given the vast differences in income, vulnerability, and resilience between countries, as well as the need for unanimity and voluntary contributions on the UN level. Relating national to international policies has the potential to be especially rewarding in this context given the SDGs relevance for and acceptance in national as well as international politics. Insights from the analysis of institutions in traditional economic sectors (e.g. on the efficiency of capital markets) should be transferred and applied to the global level (e.g. with respect to investment in the world’s natural capital stock).
  • Equitable use of the environment We place equity and fairness in dealing with the natural environment on the priority list of our challenges because first and foremost equity is a central requirement for sustainability of development. By definition, sustainable development seeks an equitable treatment across different generations as well as agents living today. We also believe that for successful environmental policies, equity and fairness are crucial complements to the dominant efficiency requirement (Sterner 2011 ). It is a specific challenge of our field to study equity in an economic context and to demonstrate its importance for sustainability to mainstream economics and the public. The first aspect of the problem is the aforementioned unequal vulnerability of countries to environmental changes such as global warming. If vulnerability is higher in less developed countries, the equity perspective is especially striking. As a matter of fact, most of the climate vulnerable countries have a low average income. Global environmental policy is then motivated not only by efficiency but also by the aim of preventing increasing inequalities (Bretschger 2017a ). Global efforts are also indicated to avoid adverse feedback effects of induced inequalities like environmental migration. The second aspect is that acceptance of public policies sharply increases with the perceived fairness of the measure (Pittel and Rübbelke 2011 ; IPCC 2018 ). In the past, economists have often underestimated political resistance against efficient environmental protection, which was mostly related to negative impacts on income distribution. Take carbon pricing and emission regulation as a current example. Although evidence from cross-country studies suggests that regressivity of carbon pricing is much less frequent than often assumed in the public (Parry 2015 ), the perceived distributional impact is often very different (Beck et al. 2016 ). Therefore the impact of environmental policies on income groups, regions, and countries should be better integrated in our analysis and policy recommendations. Where efficient policies are regressive, economists have to evaluate and propose alternative or complementary policy designs. Benefits and costs need to be disaggregated by group (country) with a special attention on the poorest members of society (countries). Internationally, equity concerns need to be addressed especially in situations where the entire world benefits from the protection of natural capital and ecosystem services in poor countries (e.g., of carbon sinks and biodiversity hubs like tropical rain forests). The experience with the REDD+ process shows the complexity of designing such international approaches to incentivize and enable developing countries to protect these global public goods. More economic analysis is needed on all of the above aspects, giving rise to a rich research agenda in theory and applied work.
  • Loss of biodiversity and natural capital The rate of species extinction today is estimated to be up to 1000 times higher than without human interference (Rockstrom 2009 ). Human activities impact biodiversity through land use change, pollution, habit fragmentation and the introduction of non-native species but also increasingly through climate change and its interaction with already existing drivers of biodiversity change (IPCC 2002 ). In view of this, biodiversity conservation has long been a focus of politics. In 1992, the United Nations Convention on Biological Diversity main objectives were stated as ”the conservation of biological diversity, the sustainable use of its components and the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising out of the utilization of genetic resources” (UN - United Nations 1992 ). Yet, although economists have developed conceptual and theoretical frameworks addressing the valuation of biodiversity (Weitzman 1998 ; Brock and Xepapadeas 2003 ) and despite data on valuation having become increasingly available (see, e.g. TEEB 2020 ), Weitzman ( 2014 ) points out, that an objective or even widely agreed measure of biodiversity and its value is still missing. The same holds for an underlying theory framework and a comprehensive measure of natural capital that not only includes biodiversity but also its links to regulating services (e.g., pollution abatement, land protection), material provisioning services (e.g., food, energy, materials), and nonmaterial services (e.g., aesthetics, experience, learning, physical and mental health, recreation). How biodiversity and natural capital should be measured, which societal, political and economic values underlie different measures and valuation and how ecological and economical trade-offs should be dealt with are big challenges left for future research. In order to address these issues, not only do we need to develop appropriate assessment methods, but we also need to disclose the theoretical basics of this assessment and which trade-offs go hand in hand with different assessments (Brei et al. 2020 ; Antoci et al. 2019 ; Drupp 2018 ). Completely new issues for the valuation of biodiversity and natural capital arise with the development of new technologies. Take DSI (digital sequence information), for example. DSI are digital images of genetic resources (DNA) that can be stored in databases. This gives rise not only to new challenges regarding their valuation but also about the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits arising out of the utilization of these resources.
  • Valuing and paying for ecosystem services Related to the question of biodiversity valuation is the market and non-market valuation of ecosystem services in general and the adequate design of payment for ecosystem services (PES). Overall, research on ecosystem services valuation has made significant progress in the last decades. Nevertheless, challenges remain even in traditional valuation fields (for example, valuation of non-use or interconnected ecosystems). Other, so far underresearched areas that constitute promising fields for future research are health-related valuation aspects (Bratman et al. 2019 ) and nonmaterial ecosystem services, such as amenities of landscapes or cultural ecosystem services (Small et al. 2017 ; James 2015 ). Also, data availability remains a problem in many valuation areas. Although digitized observation and information systems offer large potentials for previously unknown data access, they also raise a whole slew of new ethical, privacy as well as economic questions, especially in areas like health. While a lot of progress has been made in the valuation of ecosystem services, their impact on decision making still lags behind. One factor contributing to this disconnect are prevalent mismatches between regional and temporal scales of economic, institutional and ecological systems that make valuation and policy design complex (Schirpke et al. 2019 ). The challenge is to develop combined natural science-economic models that allow better insights into how changes in economic systems lead to changes in the flows of ecosystem services and vice versa (Verburg et al. 2016 ). This requires a deep understanding of ecological and economic systems as well as other aspects like technologies, regional heterogeneity and system boundaries, i.e. catastrophic events. It also raises classic economic problems, such as choosing an appropriate discount rate and degree of risk aversion. Regarding tools to include ecosystem services in economic decision making, PES are a, by now, well-established (Salzman et al. 2018 ) and also quite well-researched approach for promoting environmental outcomes. Still, the literature has identified a number of aspects to be addressed in the design of PES to make them more effective as well as efficient and to simultaneously improve social outcomes (Wunder et al. 2018 ; Chan et al. 2017 ). A promising area of research rarely addressed are PES to preserve transboundary or global ecosystem services through international payment schemes (for example, in tropical forest preservation). While some work has been done on the conceptual level (e.g. Harstad 2012 ), the REDD+ process (Maniatis et al. 2019 ) and the failure of the Yasuni initiative (Sovacool and Scarpaci 2016 ) show the complexity of such approaches for which a thorough economics analysis is still missing.
  • Conflicts over natural resources Climate change and decarbonization transform regional and global geopolitical landscapes and might give rise to future domestic as well as international conflicts (Mach et al. 2019 ; Carleton and Hsiang 2016 ). First, decarbonization changes the role of resources and of resource- and energy-related infrastructures. Climate policies affect the rent allocation between different fossil fuels like, for example, coal and natural gas, but might also change the overall rent level (Kalkuhl and Brecha 2013 ). Asset stranding can endanger stability in resource (rent) dependent countries. Conflicts may also arise over materials critical to new, low-carbon energy technologies like rare earth elements but also over access to sustainable energy (Goldthau et al. 2019 ; O’Sullivan et al. 2017 ). Further research is needed to design policies that are better equipped to reduce the vulnerability of economies to changes in resource availability and resource rents. This opens up challenges for future research, especially as restrictions from very diverse institutional capacities have to be considered to render policies efficient and effective. Second, climate change will affect the ability to meet basic human needs through food, land and water. Sulemanaa et al. ( 2019 ) find a positive effect of the occurrence of temperature extremes on conflict incidence. They stress the need for more advanced spatial econometric models to identify effects that are transmitted across space. More research is also needed on the role of institutions and interaction with other phenomena like population dynamics, migration, and environmental degradation. Currently, the role of climate for conflict is still small compared to other causes, many linkages between conflicts and climate change as well as other factors promoting conflict are still uncertain (Mach et al. 2019 ). The challenge to economic research is to get early insights into the nexus of historical and cultural factors, vested interests, population dynamics and climate change in order to help to prevent resource-related conflicts.
  • Population development and use of the environment Already since antiquity, demographic analysis has been a central topic of human thinking. With the Malthusian predictions of catastrophes caused by population growth, the topic is firmly related to the natural environment and the limits of planet Earth. While limited food production was the dominant topic in the 18th century, the impact of world population on global commons, availability of renewable and exhaustible resources, and ecosystem services have been dominant topics in the last decades. Still, while it is often argued in the public and in natural sciences that world population size should be a concern because of ecological constraints, economics has largely left the topic on the side; the few exceptions (Peretto and Valente 2015 ) and (Bretschger 2013 , 2020 ) point in a different direction, namely the compatibility of population growth and sustainable development under very general conditions. Current trends of demographic transition show significant signs of population degrowth for leading economies while trends for developing countries vary substantially (UN - United Nations 2019 ). Population is forecasted to expand especially in Africa, accounting for more than half of the world’s population growth over the coming decades, raising questions about the effect of this population increase on fragile ecosystems, resource use and ultimately the potential for sustainable growth (African Development Bank 2015 ). Population growth will also promote further urbanization and migration triggered by environmental and resource depletion but also giving rise to new environmental problems (Awumbila 2017 ). Challenges from population development and environment are thus closely linked to the other research topics highlighted in this article. However, population growth is not exogenously given but determined by economic, social as well as environmental factors. Education and income or economic development have long been established as crucial for fertility (see e.g. the reviews of the literature provided by Kan and Lee 2018 ; Fox et al. 2019 ). To integrate these findings into a holistic approach is a mediating challenge for future research. Climate change might affect these channels in different ways, potentially exacerbating global inequality (Casey et al. 2019 ). However, population development, fertility, and mortality are not only affected by climate change but also by other environmental stresses like air pollution (Conforti et al. 2018 ). A successful combination of endogenous fertility and mortality with natural resource scarcity, agricultural production, and pollution accumulation as well as capital and knowledge build-up in a comprehensive framework is a respectable challenge for an economic modeller; we suggest that in the future it should be considered by economists more intensively.
  • Land use and soil degradation The terrestrial biosphere with its products, functions and ecosystem services is the foundation of human existence, not only for food security but far beyond. Currently, about a quarter of ice-free land area is degraded by human impacts (IPCC 2019 ). The optimal use of scarce land resources becomes an even more urgent topic in the face of the biodiversity crisis and the onset of climate change. This holds especially as the physical and economic access to sufficient, safe and nutritious food is the basic precondition for human existence. Climate change challenges this access on different levels. On the one hand, climate change increases the pressure on productive land areas (due to extreme weather events such as droughts, floods, forest fires or the shifting of climatic zones). On the other hand, land plays a major role in many climate protection scenarios by reducing emissions from land use and land use change, protecting carbon stocks in soils and ecosystems, and conserving and expanding natural carbon sinks. Also, the capture and storage of CO 2 through carbon dioxide removal technologies plays an increasing role for reaching the Paris climate goals (IPCC 2018 ). The induced increase in the demand for the different services from land inevitably implies trade-offs. However, neither the trade-offs nor the potentials for synergic uses are, as of now, comprehensively understood from an economic point of view and thus pose a challenge for future research. While there is a growing literature on negative emission technologies, their costs, potentials and side effects (Fuss et al. 2019 and references within) as well as on the interaction between climate goals and other SGDs on the global level (von Stechow et al. 2016 ), many research questions still remain to be addressed (Minx et al. 2018 ). This concerns especially a better understanding of opportunity costs, governance requirements, regional and distributional effects as well as of acceptance and ethical considerations. With respect to land degradation and land use for food production, changing climate and weather conditions as well as regional population pressure may raise the rate of land degradation (Fezzi and Bateman 2015 ), hurting food security and calling for preservation policies (Brausmann and Bretschger 2018 ). The overuse of ecosystems like forests and water, which protect and complement land, can accelerate the risk of adverse shocks and thus lower soil fertility, which reveals the close link between the different research subjects. However, much of the agricultural research in this field is still quite distant from mainstream environmental economics which can harm research productivity substantially. It remains a challenge to integrate agricultural and environmental research better, for example by bringing together food production, population, and the environment into a macrodynamic framework (Lanz et al. 2017 ).
  • Environmental migration Migration in times of climate change is an extraordinarily complex, multicausal and controversial challenge (Adger et al. 2014 ). Heatwaves, droughts, hurricanes, and rising sea levels are likely to motivate or even force a growing number of people to leave their homes moving to presumably safer places. Climate-related migration can take a variety of different forms (Warner 2011) from voluntary to involuntary, from short- to long-distance and from temporary to permanent. Migration decisions are usually based on different motives and personal circumstances (climatically, politically, economically, socially), leading to heterogeneous reactions to climate events and making it often problematic to identify and delineate climate-induced migration. Due to these and other methodological difficulties and the small number of studies so far, no globally reliable forecasts for climate induced migration exist (WBGU - German Advisory Council on Global Change 2018a , b ). At present, the forecasted magnitude of the phenomenon ranges from 25 million up to 1 billion people by 2050 (Ionesco et al. 2017 ). Much of this migration can be expected to take place within countries, for example, from rural to urban areas or from drylands to coastal zones (Henderson et al. 2014 ) with environmental migration being one possible adaptation and survivor strategy in the face of climate change (Millock 2015 ). Given the uncertainty in future migration projections, the challenge is to improve migration models (Cattaneo et al. 2019 ) which includes a better understanding and integration of the microfoundation of agents’ migration decisions. Migration, and especially mass-migration, can have a profound impact on the environment of the new as well as the old settlement location and on their economic structure. Labor and commodities markets will be affected the most, with challenges arising also for education and health systems, government budgets and public spending. By affecting public institutions and the skill-mix of the labor force, migration alters economic development both in the sending and in the receiving countries or regions. More research is needed on these impacts. The influx of environmental migrants to new settlement locations may also trigger hostile attitudes and lead to clashes and even armed conflicts. The migrants may be perceived as rivals for scarce resources (land, clean water) or jobs. The situation may be aggravated by lack of political stability and poor-quality political institutions. Dealing with these aspects gives rise to new challenges in environment and resource economics. Traditional analysis of economic costs and benefits of migration have to be complemented by behavioral economic and political economy analyses.
  • Urbanization as a key for environmental development In the last 70 years, the urban population has increased fivefold with more than half of the world’s population living in cities today and forecasts projecting the share of urban population to rise to almost 70% in 2050 (UN - United Nations 2018 ). Cities are responsible for about 70% of the world energy use and global CO 2 -emissions (Seto et al. 2014 ) and ecological footprints are positively correlated to the degree of urbanization (WBGU - German Advisory Council on Global Change 2016 ). In 2014, about 880 million people were living in slums (UN - United Nations 2016 ) elucidating the problems to make urban development environmentally as well as economically and socially sustainable. The speed of urbanization is projected to be the fastest in low and middle income countries, especially in Africa and Asia (UN - United Nations 2018 ), leading to new challenges for the provision of infrastructure, housing, energy supply, transport and even health care. Climate change can be expected to not only foster urbanization trends (Henderson et al. 2017 ) but also increase the magnitude of urbanization-related challenges. Urban areas are often located close to the coast or rivers basins, making them susceptible to rising sea levels and impacts of extreme weather events. Risks can be expected to be higher for poor households due to settlement in less safe areas and poorer housing (Barata et al. 2011 ), potentially perpetuating existing inequalities. On the other hand, cities might offer more efficient adaptation potentials. To date the consequences of climate change for cities and urbanization are still to be determined in detail but depend heavily on factors like location, size and level of development as well as governance capacities. Making cities, their population and their infrastructure resilient to climate change will be decisive for future development. The main challenge here is to better connect the research fields of environmental and urban economics to understand the drivers and dynamic effects of climate change on urbanization and resulting economic development, on adaptation costs and benefits and on the role of institutions. Insights from regional, political and behavioral economics can help shape effective governance to enhance resilience of cities to climate change.
  • Health and epidemiological environment Environmental degradation can have profound implications for human health. These implications lead to direct as well as indirect challenges for economic decision making, economic development and thus economic research. While many of these challenges might not be new per se, they can be severely exacerbated by, for example, climate change. Economic implications of long-term increases in vector-borne diseases and heat stress as well as pandemics like the COVID-19 and ozone formation still remain to be analyzed in depth, as do the costs and benefits of adaptation measures dedicated to mitigating these effects (Mendelsohn 2012 ). Climate change also affects human health indirectly through impacts on economic development, land use, and biodiversity - and vice versa. Failed emission reductions and bad environmental management especially impact developing countries negatively through direct effects on health but also through health effects of delayed poverty reduction (Fankhauser and Stern 2020 ). Exposure to diseases or epidemics can increase the risk of civil conflicts and violence (Cervellati et al. 2016 , 2018 ). While research has addressed effects of life-expectancy, diseases and premature mortality on long-run economic development (e.g. Ebenstein et al. 2015 ; Acemoglu and Johnson 2007 ), a thorough analysis of the climate-health-development nexus is still missing. Overall, most research carried out on the interaction between environment, climate and human health has focused on physical health and mortality. The effects of air pollution from the burning of fossil fuels or agriculture on premature deaths, cardiac conditions and respiratory diseases, for example, received not only renewed interest in the wake of recent scandals (see e.g. Alexander and Schwandt 2019 ) but have been an active field of research for a number of years (Schlenker and Walker 2016 ; Tschofen et al. 2019 ). Mental health implications like stress, anxiety or depression on the other hand have received much less attention although, for example, Chen et al. ( 2018 ) in a study on air pollution in China estimate these effects to be on a similar scale to costs arising from impacts on physical health. Also, Danzer and Danzer ( 2016 ) find substantial effects of a large energy-related disaster (the Chernobyl catastrophe) on subjective well-being and mental health. Economic research should take up the challenge and put more effort into the economic evaluation of mental health related effects of climate change and environmental degradation in general. Potential to analyze these and other health-related questions have risen substantially in the last years, method-wise as well as topical, with new large data sets becoming available. Big data from insurance companies, satellite imagery on pollution dispersion and effects of draughts, for example, can provide new insights into the dynamics between environmental changes and health. But digital technologies themselves also generate new research questions addressing, for example, risks, costs and benefits of these new technologies.
  • Carbon exposure and green finance The impact of climate change and of climate policy on the financial system is a topic of increasing public concern. The transition to a low-carbon economy poses a lot of challenges not only from physical risks and damages but also from transition risks. These accrue in such different areas as climate-related policy making, altered market behavior, changes in international trade patterns, technology development, and consumer behavior. To support a safe and gradual transition to a low-carbon economy, the financial sector needs to evaluate and eventually address the new risks associated with climate change and decarbonization in an efficient manner. There is widespread concern that financial markets currently lack sufficient information about the carbon exposure of assets, resulting in risks from climate change and climate policy for investments (Karydas and Xepapadeas 2018 ). If not anticipated by the markets, climate shocks also cause asset stranding, i.e. unanticipated and premature capital write-offs, downward revaluations, and conversion of assets to liabilities (Rozenberg et al. 2020 ; Bretschger and Soretz 2018 ). The same holds true for climate policies which are not or cannot be correctly anticipated by investors (Dietz et al. 2016 ; Stolbova et al. 2018 ; Sen and von Schickfus 2020 ). The growing awareness of these risks is reflected in the attention that policy makers have devoted to the development of transparency improving information systems and indicators in recent years. However, challenges related the design of these systems and indicators, e.g. with respect to an accurate and encompassing risk assessment, still remain. The importance of addressing these challenges is excerbated by prevalent network effects and counterparty risks that transmit climate-induced financial shocks from individual firms to the broad public holding their capital in stocks of fossil-fuel-related firms, investment funds, and pension funds, which all could suffer from stranded assets (Battiston et al. 2017 ). Divestment campaigns, shareholder engagement, and mandatory disclosure of climate-relevant financial information by companies and investors warrant further theoretical and empirical analysis. Also, a better understanding of the economics behind financing instruments like green bonds is only recently emerging (Agliardi and Agliardi 2019 ). Despite some early studies there is a knowledge gap with respect to the extent of climate and policy risks for central banks and regarding the potential significance of different channels connecting the risks in the real economy with monetary policy. Given the environmental and international policy perspective of the climate problem, the specific contribution of the financial sector and the central banks in the architecture of global climate policy has to be subject to further investigation.
  • Energy system transformation The transition from a fossil-based to a green economy is needed to combat climate change but requires a thorough transformation of energy systems (Pommeret and Schubert 2019 ) in developed as well as in developing countries. In industrialized countries, challenges arise from the structural transformation of highly complex energy systems and their linkage with other economic sectors. While one hundred years ago, it was the rapid dissemination of fossil-based industrial processes, transportation, and heating that resulted in wide-spread sectoral change, similar adjustments can be expected with the increasing importance of electricity for decarbonization. However, changing the use of energy technologies in practice involves decisions on different levels and constitutes a highly nonlinear process. Future power generation in many countries will increasingly rely on renewable energies like wind and solar energy. To offset intermittent power generation, more and better storage capacities of batteries or pumped hydropower will be needed (Ambec and Crampes 2019 ). Synthetic fuels, heat pumps, fuel cells and e-mobility will increasingly use electricity to replace fossil fuels not only in the power sector but also in traffic and heat generation. While the adoption of renewable technologies like wind and solar was often much faster than predicted in the past, the critical mass of market penetration has still to be reached in other areas to benefit from potential scale effects and cost decreases. Shape and speed of the energy transition are, however, highly dependent on a political process which is hard to predict for market participants. Policy and ecological risks, together with the long-run character of the energy and related infrastructure investments, pose a big challenge for research and practice. In this context, it is especially the economic potential of green hydrogen and/or synthetic fuels that is controversially discussed at present. As production costs are expected to fall (Glenk and Reichelstein 2019 ), interest in hydrogen is increasing sharply (IEA 2019 ) and new research questions arise. For developing countries, clean and decentralized renewable energy technologies offer big potentials for electrification and economic development. However, despite the potential for decarbonization and the reduction of other externalities and health hazards and despite the fact that more than 90% of the annual increase in power generation comes from emerging economies, research on the development and adoption of clean energy technologies still focuses mainly on the developed world. More research on the barriers and challenges for adoption in developing countries is needed, including sustainable financing, institutional framing and the design of regionally tailored policies.
  • Sustainability perspective on digitalization Digitalization and artificial intelligence are often seen as opportunities for enhancing the efficiency of energy and resource use. They offer new opportunities for circular economy, agriculture, monitoring of ecosystems and biodiversity, sustainable finance and decarbonization (see WBGU 2019 and literature within). However, they may also accelerate energy and resource use, increase inequality between regions and income groups and endanger sustainable development. Digitalization offers new access to markets, impacts market forms and shapes consumer behavior all of which can have extensive implications for the ecological, social and economic dimensions of sustainable development. Digitalization is a cross-cutting theme that reaches across spatial scales (from regional development to globalization) as well as temporal scales (from short-run impacts on energy systems to long-run adaptation to climate change). So far, the potentials and challenges for sustainable development that are associated with digital technologies have mostly been addressed outside of environmental and resource economics. The focus has been on topics such as data security and privacy or, for example, on the implications of the ”fourth industrial revolution” on employment and labor markets. Costs and benefits of digitization, the design and effectiveness of policies in industrialized as well as developing countries have garnered much less attention in the context of environmental, resource, energy and climate economics. Also, impacts of digitization on the behavior of economic agents resulting in, for example, rebound effects or changes in consumption patterns and environmental awareness, have not been addressed comprehensively (Gossar 2015 ). In all of these areas, our limited knowledge base creates opportunities and challenges for future research in the field. But, digitalization not only creates new research questions, it also provides new means to answer them. It has led to new developments in data science, big data analysis, machine learning and artificial intelligence that allow new insights into, for example, material flows, emission patterns and technology diffusion as well as the optimal design, implementation and effectiveness of regulation (Fowlie et al. 2019 ; Weersink et al. 2018 ; Graziano and Gillingham 2015 ).
  • Quantitative analysis of environmental use Recently, there has been a significant shift in the empirical methods used in economics from traditional regression analysis to random assignment and quasi-experiments. Arguably this can improve the capturing of causal relationships and reduce the biases of traditional study designs. In environmental economics, experimental and quasi-experimental approaches have been applied mainly for capturing individuals’ or firms’ decisions on the use of land, water, resources, and energy (e.g. Allcott 2011 ; Duflo et al. 2013 ; Deschenes et al. 2017 ). Wider applications of these rigorous methods in environmental economics and well-suited empirical designs are desirable but certainly challenging e.g. when assessing aggregate environmental costs from climate change or biodiversity loss. An important but underrated field in applied environmental economics is the ex-post empirical assessment of environmental policies. The challenge is not only to identify environmental externalities, causalities, and impact intensities but also to provide an accurate valuation of the cost of policies, because they vary widely especially in environmental economics. The traditional empirical methods remain to be important and are not simply replaced. The same holds true for empirical designs in a time, cross-country, or panel structure. The increasing availability of large or very large datasets with observations varying widely across time and space offers a different set of options to provide evidence on the impact of environmental damages or policies to abate them (e.g. Currie and Walker 2011 ; Martin et al. 2014 ; Zhang et al. 2018 ). Fast-growing computational power and machine learning provide even more avenues for fruitful applications in environmental economics (see e.g. Abrell et al. 2019 ) but the challenge to use computer power wisely and to derive results which are sufficiently robust remains demanding .
  • Structural assessment modelling and modelling transparency In an effort to better understand the ramifications of political decisions and technological developments on climate change, energy supply and resource extraction (to name but a few examples), increasingly sophisticated numerical models have been developed in recent decades. It is evident that quantitative economics analysis is important for policy advice. Yet despite their complexity, these models usually still adopt some very simplifying and sometimes ad-hoc assumptions. In particular assumptions used in integrated valuation models have come under heavy criticism in recent years (Stern 2013 ; Pindyck 2013 ). Simplifications concern market structures and market failures, the integration of risk and uncertainty as well as societal, institutional and cultural detail. Also, manifestations of climate change and damages come at very different regional and temporal scales, making a truly integrated assessment of the climate-ecosystem-economy nexus next to impossible. We see it as a major challenge for future research to provide more accurate foundations for integrated assessment models. While simplifications are needed to reduce computational complexity, they raise the question to which extent the results obtained render reliable insights into future developments. Asking for models that are detailed in every dimension and can answer every question resembles of course the search for the holy grail. However, the need for a better understanding of the model dynamics has already led to the development of a new generation of models which have a stronger foundation in theory (Golosov et al. 2014 , Bretschger and Karydas 2019 ). A better understanding of the limits of models and of the questions specific models can and cannot address is still needed as well as transparency in model development. More applied studies, assessments of global environmental trends under different economic assumptions often use ”scenarios” to describe future trajectories. The scenarios are mostly based on expert opinion and do not rely on estimates about the likelihood that such a trajectory will occur. It is also critical that the economics behind the scenarios is often neglected. Prominently, per capita income can be projected using endogenous growth theory, while population development can be evaluated using state-of-the-art theories on fertility and morbidity.

Conclusions

This article set out to highlight a number of challenges that are highly relevant for future research in the field of environmental and resource economics. The focus was mainly, although not exclusively, on topical issues. We only briefly touched upon on some methodological advancements that might have the power to further parts of our field. Big data, machine learning and artificial intelligence hold high promise in this regard but their limits and potentials for environment, climate and resource economics have yet to be fully understood.

It should have become clear, that a number of the challenges presented can only be addressed adequately by interdisciplinary research teams with relevant disciplines ranging from climate science, (computer) engineering, sociology, virology to soil sciences. In many cases, economists’ analysis and the derivation of sound policy recommendations require the knowledge available in these fields. However, such research cooperations are by no means one-way streets: Other disciplines need the input of economists in order to assess future development scenarios and implementability of solutions. The knowledge and data required for economics analysis does not always exist yet, but interdisciplinary cooperation can help to identify and close these gaps. Overall, the less economists have already worked on specific challenges, the harder it is to assess best research strategies and the potential for success. Take the digitization-sustainable-development-nexus as an example: best research strategies and success are extremely difficult to predict as not only is the related economics research still in its infancy but also the field itself is extremely dynamic.

As already pointed out in the beginning: We are aware that our selection is bound to create discontent and disagreement. Having said this, it should also be stated that we expect some of our challenges to be more or less universally agreed upon. This holds especially for the broader topics: for example, how to accomplish deep decarbonization; how to deal with risk and uncertainty; or how to assess the role of disruptive development. One reason for this lies in the encompassing nature of these topics. They are relevant for many of the other fields that we have pointed out: For behavioral analyses, the capacity to deal with disruptive change in the face of risk and uncertainty are essential. Loss of biodiversity and natural capital, land degradation, conflicts over resources and migration are exacerbated by climate change. The potential of digitization for sustainable development constitutes disruptive change in itself. Yet, all of these fields are not merely subfields of the more overarching themes, they raise important research questions in their own right.

Nevertheless, it is to be expected that it will be the more specific fields over which disagreement will arise: Are ‘land use and soil degradation’ more important than ‘fisheries’? Is the ‘institutional analysis of environmental policies’ of higher relevance than the ‘development of alternative welfare concepts’ (to pick out some random examples). Of course, there are more fields that could have been included and also, of course, there is no objective criterion for the inclusion or exclusion of fields. The selection of the challenges is based on the analysis and criteria presented in the first section but it is ultimately ours; we are happy if this paper contributes to a lively and constructive discussion about the future of our field.

Open access funding provided by Swiss Federal Institute of Technology Zurich.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Contributor Information

Lucas Bretschger, Email: hc.zhte@reghcsterbl .

Karen Pittel, Email: ed.ofi@lettip .

  • Abrell J, Kosch M, Rausch S (2019) How effective was the UK carbon tax? A machine learning approach to policy evaluation, CER-ETH working paper 19/317, ETH Zurich
  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S. Disease and development: the effect of life expectancy on economic growth. J Polit Econ. 2007; 115 (6):925–985. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA. Economic backwardness in political perspective. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2006; 100 (1):115–131. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Acemoglu D, Philippe Aghion P, Bursztyn L, Hemous D. The environment and directed technical change. Am Econ Rev. 2012; 102 (1):131–166. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Adger NM, Pulhin JM, Barnett J, Dabelko GD, Hovelsrud GK, Levy M, White LL (Eds) (2014) Climate change 2014: impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability. Part a: global and sectoral aspects. Contribution of working group II to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
  • African Development Bank (2015) African Ecological Futures Report 2015, https://www.afdb.org
  • Aghion P, Dechezleprêtre A, Hémous D, Martin R, Van Reenen J. Carbon taxes, path dependency, and directed technical change: evidence from the auto industry. J Polit Econ. 2016; 124 (1):1–51. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Agliardi E, Xepapadeas A (2018) Optimal scheduling of greenhouse gas emissions under carbon budgeting and policy design, Athens University of Economics and Business, DEOS Working Paper No. 1808
  • Agliardi E, Agliardi R (2019) Financing environmentally-sustainable projects with green bonds, Environment and Development Economics 24, Special Issue 6 (The Economics of Climate Change and Sustainability (Part A)), pp 608–662
  • Alexander D, Schwandt H (2019) The impact of car pollution on infant and child health: evidence from emissions cheating, WP 2019-04, The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
  • Allcott H. Social norms and energy conservation. J Public Econ. 2011; 95 (9–10):1082–1095. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ambec S, Crampes C. Decarbonizing electricity generation with intermittent sources of energy. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ. 2019; 6 (6):1105–1134. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Antoci A, Borghesi S, Russu P. Don’t feed the bears! environmental defense expenditures and species-typical behaviour in an optimal growth model. Macroecon Dyn. 2019 doi: 10.1017/S1365100519000397. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Arthur WB. Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Econ J. 1989; 99 (394):116–131. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Athanassoglou S, Xepapadeas A. Pollution control with uncertain stock dynamics: When, and how, to be precautious. J Environ Econ Manage. 2012; 63 :304–320. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Auffhammer M. The state of environmental and resource economics: a google scholar perspective. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2009; 3 (2):251–269. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Awumbila M. Drivers of migration and urbanization in Africa: key trends and issues. background paper prepared for UN expert group meeting on sustainable cities. New York: Human Mobility and International Migration; 2017. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Badeeb RA, Lean HH, Clark J. The evolution of the natural resource curse thesis: a critical literature survey. Resour Policy. 2017; 51 :123–134. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barata M, Ligeti E, De Simone G, Dickinson T, Jack D, Penney J, Rahman M, Zimmerman R (2011) In: Climate change and human health in cities. Climate change and cities: first assessment report of the urban climate Change Research Network. Rosenzweig C, Solecki WD, Hammer SA Mehrotra S (eds) Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
  • Barnes W, Gartland M, Stack M. Old habits die hard: path dependency and behavioral lock-in. J Econ Issues. 2004; 38 (2):371–377. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Battiston S, Mandel A, Monasterolo I, Schutze F, Visentin G. A climate stress-test of the financial system. Nat Clim Change. 2017; 7 (4):283–288. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Baumgärtner S, Engler J-O (2018) 2018. An axiomatic foundation of entropic preferences under Knightian uncertainty, Paper presented at the SURED conference in Ascona
  • Beck M, Rivers N, Yonezawa H. A rural myth? Sources and implications of the perceived unfairness of carbon taxes in rural communities. Ecol Econ. 2016; 124 :124–134. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Borissov K, Brausmann A, Bretschger L. Carbon pricing, technology transition, and skill-based development. Eur Econ Rev. 2019; 118 :252–269. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bratman GN, Anderson CB, Berman MG, Cochran B, de Vries S, Flanders J, Daily GC. Nature and mental health: an ecosystem service perspective. Sci Adv. 2019 doi: 10.1126/sciadv.aax0903. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brausmann A, Bretschger L. Economic development on a finite planet with stochastic soil degradation. Eur Econ Rev. 2018; 108 :1–19. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brei M, Pérez-Barahona A, Strobl E. Protecting species through legislation: the case of sea turtles. Am J Agric Econ. 2020; 102 (1):300–328. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L. Population growth and natural resource scarcity: long-run development under seemingly unfavourable conditions. Scand J Econ. 2013; 115 (3):722–755. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L. Equity and the convergence of nationally determined climate policies. Environ Econ Policy Stud. 2017; 19 (1):1–14. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L. Climate policy and economic growth. Resour Energy Econ. 2017; 49 :1–15. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L. Malthus in the light of climate change. Eur Econ Rev. 2020; 127 :103477. doi: 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2020.103477. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L, Schaefer A. Dirty history versus clean expectations: Can energy policies provide momentum for growth? Eur Econ Rev. 2017; 99 :170–190. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bretschger L, Vinogradova A (2018) Escaping Damocles’ Sword: endogenous climate shocks in a growing economy, economics working paper series 18/291, ETH Zurich
  • Bretschger L, Soretz S (2018) Stranded assets: how policy uncertainty affects capital, growth, and the environment, economics working paper series 18/288, ETH Zurich
  • Bretschger L, Karydas C. Economics of climate change: Introducing the basic climate economic (BCE) model. Environ Develop Econ. 2019; 24 (6):560–582. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brock W, Xepapadeas A. Valuing biodiversity from an economic perspective: a unified economic. Ecol Genet Approach Am Econ Rev. 2003; 93 :597–1614. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brock W, Xepapadeas A (1903) (2019) Regional climate policy under deep uncertainty: robust control. Athens University of Economics and Business, Discussion Paper No, Hot Spots and Learning
  • Bromley D. Economic interests and institutions: the conceptual foundations of public policy. Oxford: Blackwell; 1989. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cai Y, Lenton TM, Lontzek TS. Risk of multiple interacting tipping points should encourage rapid CO2 emission reduction. Nat Clim Change. 2016; 6 :520–525. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Calel R, Dechezlepretre A. Environmental policy and directed technological change: evidence from the European carbon market. Rev Econ Stat. 2016; 98 (1):173–191. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Carleton TA, Hsiang SM. Social and economic impacts of climate. Science. 2016 doi: 10.1126/science.aad9837. [ PubMed ] [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Casari M, Luini L. Cooperation under alternative punishment institutions: an experiment. J Econ Behav Organ. 2009; 71 (2):273–282. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Casey G, Shayegh S, Moreno-Cruz J, Bunzl M, Galor O, Caldeira K. The impact of climate change on fertility. Environ Res Lett. 2019 doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/ab0843. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cattaneo C, Beine M, Fröhlich CJ, Kniveton D, Martinez-Zarzoso I, Mastrorillo M, Millock K, Piguet E, Schraven B. Human migration in the era of climate change. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2019; 13 (2):189–206. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cerda Planas L. Moving toward greener societies: moral motivation and green behaviour. Environ Resource Econ. 2018; 70 :835–860. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cervellati M, Esposito E, Sunde U, Valmori S (2018) Malaria and violence. Econ Policy, pp 403–446
  • Cervellati M, Sunde U, Valmori S. Pathogens, weather shocks and civil conflicts. Econ J. 2016; 127 :2581–616. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chan K, Anderson E, Chapman M, Jespersen K, Olmsted P. Payments for ecosystem services: rife with problems and potential - for transformation towards sustainability. Ecol Econ. 2017; 140 :110–122. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chen Z, Oliva P, Zhang P (2018) Pollution and mental health: evidence from China, NBER Working Paper Series 24686
  • Conforti A, Mascia M, Cioffi G, De Angelis C, Coppola G, De Rosa P, Pivonello R, Alviggi C, De Placido G. Air pollution and female fertility: a systematic review of literature. Reproduct Biol Endocrinol. 2018; 16 :117. doi: 10.1186/s12958-018-0433-z. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Costanza R, Howarth R, Kubiszewski I, Liu S, Ma C, Plumecocq G, Stern D. Influential publications in ecological economics revisited. Ecol Econ. 2016; 123 :68–76. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Currie J, Walker R. Traffic congestion and infant health: evidence from E-ZPass. Am Econ J Appl Econ. 2011; 3 (1):65–90. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Danzer AM, Danzer N. The long-run consequences of chernobyl: evidence on subjective well-being, mental health and welfare. J Public Econ. 2016; 135 (2016):47–60. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Dasgupta P, Heal G. The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources. Rev Econ Stud. 1974; 41 (5):3–28. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Dasgupta S, De Cian E (2016) Institutions and the environment: existing evidence and future directions, FEEM Working Paper No. 41.2016
  • Deschenes O, Greenstone M, Shapiro JS. Defensive investments and the demand for air quality: evidence from the NOx budget program. Am Econ Rev. 2017; 107 (10):2958–2989. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Dietz S, Bower A, Dixon C, Gradwell P. Climate value at risk of global financial assets. Nat Clim Change Lett. 2016; 6 :676–679. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Drupp MA. Limits to substitution between ecosystem services and manufactured goods and implications for social discounting. Environ Resour Econ. 2018; 69 :135–158. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Duflo E. Richard T. Ely lecture: the economist as plumber. Am Econ Rev Papers Proc. 2017; 107 (5):126. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Duflo E, Greenstone M, Pande R, Ryan N. Truth-telling by third-party auditors and the response of polluting firms: Experimental evidence from India. Q J Econ. 2013; 128 (4):1499–1545. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ebenstein A, Fan M, Greenstone M, He G, Yin P, Zhou M. Growth, pollution, and life expectancy: China from 1991 to 2012. Am Econ Rev Paper Proc. 2015; 105 (5):226–231. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ehrlich P. Key issues for attention from ecological economists. Environ Dev Econ. 2008; 13 (1):1–20. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Engel S, Pagiola S, Wunder S. Designing payments for environmental services in theory and practice: an overview of the issues. Ecol Econ. 2008; 65 :663–674. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fankhauser S. Adaptation to climate change. Ann Rev Resour Econ. 2017; 9 (1):209–230. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fankhauser S, Stern N, et al. Climate change, development, poverty and economics. In: Basu K, et al., editors. The state of economics, the state of the world. Cambridge: MIT Press; 2020. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fezzi C, Bateman I. The impact of climate change on agriculture: nonlinear effects and aggregation bias in Ricardian models of farmland values. J Assoc Environ Resour Econ. 2015; 2 (1):57–92. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fowlie M, Rubin E, Walker R. Bringing satellite-based air quality estimates down to earth. AEA Paper Proc. 2019; 109 :283–288. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fox J, Klüsener S, Myrskyla M. Is a positive relationship between fertility and economic development emerging at the sub-national regional level? Theoretical considerations and evidence from Europe. Eur J Populat. 2019; 35 :487–518. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Fuss S, Lamb WF, Callaghan MW, Hilaire J, Creutzig F, Amann T, Minx JC. Negative emissions-Part 2: costs, potentials and side effects. Environ Res Lett. 2019; 13 :063002. doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/aabf9f. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Galor O, Özak Ö. The agricultural origins of time preference. Am Econ Rev. 2016; 106 (10):3064–3103. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gerlagh R, Michielsen TO. Moving targets-cost-effective climate policy under scientific uncertainty. Clim Change. 2015; 132 :519–529. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Glenk G, Reichelstein S. Economics of converting renewable power to hydrogen. Nature Energy. 2019; 4 :216–222. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Goldthau A, Westphal K, Bazilian M, Bradshaw M. How the energy transition will reshape geopolitics. Nature. 2019; 569 :29–31. doi: 10.1038/d41586-019-01312-5. [ PubMed ] [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Golosov M, Hassler J, Krusell P, Tsyvinski A. Optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium. Econometrica. 2014; 82 (1):41–88. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gossar C (2015) Rebound Effects and ICT: a review of the literature. In: Hilty LM, Aebischer B (eds) ICT Innovations for sustainability, pp 435–448
  • Graziano M, Gillingham K. Spatial patterns of solar photovoltaic system adoption: the influence of neighbors and the built environment. J Econ Geogr. 2015; 15 (4):815–839. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hainsch K, Burandt T, Kemfert C, Löffler K, Oei PY, von Hirschhausen C (2018) Emission pathways towards a low-carbon energy system for Europe: a model-based analysis of decarbonization scenarios, DIW Discussion Paper 1745
  • Hansen LP, Sargent TJ. Robust control and model uncertainty. Am Econ Rev. 2001; 91 (2):60–66. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Harstad B. Buy Coal! A case for supply-side, environmental policy. J Polit Econ. 2012; 120 (1):77–115. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hartwick JM. Intergenerational equity and the investment of rents from exhaustible resources. Am Econ Rev. 1977; 67 :972–74. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Henderson JV, Storeygard A, Deichmann U (2014) 50 years of urbanization in Africa, Examining the Role of Climate Change. World Bank Development Research Group Policy Research Working Paper no. 6925. Washington DC: World Bank Group
  • Henderson JV, Storeygard A, Deichmann U. Has climate change driven urbanization in Africa? J Dev Econ. 2017; 124 :60–82. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hotelling H. The economics of exhaustible resources. J Polit Econ. 1931; 39 (2):137–175. [ Google Scholar ]
  • IEA (2019) The Future of Hydrogen, International Energy Agency https://www.iea.org/hydrogen2019
  • Ionesco D, Mokhnacheva D, Gemenne F. The atlas of environmental migration. London: International Organization for Migration; 2017. [ Google Scholar ]
  • IPCC (2002) Climate Change and Biodiversity, IPCC Technocal Paper V, https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/03/climate-changes-biodiversity-en.pdf
  • IPCC (2018) Summary for Policymakers. In: Global warming of 1 . 5 ∘ C. An IPCC Special Report on the impacts of global warming of 1 . 5 ∘ C above pre-industrial levels and related global greenhouse gas emission pathways, World Meteorological Organization, Geneva, Switzerland
  • IPCC (2019) Special report on climate change, desertification, land degradation, sustainable land management, food security, and greenhouse gas fluxes in Terrestrial Ecosystems, Summary for Policymakers
  • James SP. Cultural ecosystem services: a critical assessment. Ethics Policy Environ. 2015; 18 (3):338–350. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Jensen S, Traeger CP. Optimal climate change mitigation under long-term growth uncertainty: Stochastic integrated assessment and analytic findings. Eur Econ Rev. 2014; 69 :104–125. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kalkuhl M, Brecha RJ. The carbon rent economics of climate policy. Energy Econ. 2013; 39 :89–99. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kalkuhl M, Edenhofer O, Lessmann K. Learning or lock-in: Optimal technology policies to support mitigation. Resour Energy Econ. 2012; 31 (1):1–23. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kan K, Lee M-J. The effects of education on fertility: evidence from Taiwan. Econ Inq. 2018; 56 (1):343–357. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Karydas C, Xepapadeas A (2018) Pricing climate change risks: CAPM with rare disasters and stochastic probabilities. CER-ETH Working Paper Series Working Paper 19/311
  • Klibanoff P, Marinacci M, Mukerji S. A smooth model of decision making under uncertainty. Econometrica. 2005; 73 (6):1849–1892. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kubea R, Löschel A, Mertense H, Requate T (2018) Research trends in environmental and resource economics: Insights from four decades of JEEM, paper presented at the WCERE 2018 in Gothenburg
  • Lanz B, Dietz S, Swanson T. Global population growth, technology, and Malthusian constraints: a quantitative growth theoretic perspective. Int Econ Rev. 2017; 58 (3):973–1006. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lenton TM, Ciscar J-C. Integrating tipping points into climate impact assessments. Clim Change. 2013; 117 :585–597. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Levin S, Xepapadeas T, Crépin A-S, Norberg J, de Zeeuw A, Folke C, Hughes T, Arrow K, Barrett S, Daily G, Ehrlich P, Kautsky N, Maeler K-G, Polasky S, Troell M, Vincent JR, Walker B. Social-ecological systems as complex adaptive systems: modeling and policy implications. Environ Dev Econ. 2013; 18 (2):111–132. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mach KJ, Kraan CM, Adger WN, Buhaug H, Burke M, Fearon JD, Field CB, Hendrix CS, Maystadt J-F, O’Loughlin J, Roessler P, Scheffran J, Schultz KA, von Uexkull N. Climate as a risk factor for armed conflict. Nature. 2019; 571 :193–197. [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Maniatis D, Scriven J, Jonckheere I, Laughlin J, Todd K. Toward REDD+ Implementation. Annu Rev Environ Resour. 2019; 44 :373–98. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Manoussi V, Xepapadeas A, Emmerling J. Climate engineering under deep uncertainty. J Econ Dyn Control. 2018; 94 :207–224. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Marin G, Vona F. Climate policies and skill-biased employment dynamics: evidence from EU countries. J Environ Econ Manage. 2019; 98 :1–18. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Martin R, De Preux LB, Wagner UJ. The impact of a carbon tax on manufacturing: evidence from microdata. J Public Econ. 2014; 117 :1–14. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mendelsohn R. The economics of adaptation to climate change in developing countries. Clim Change Econ. 2012; 3 (2):1250006-1–1250006-21. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Millock K. Migration and environment. Ann Rev Resour Econ. 2015; 7 (1):35–60. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Minx JC, Lamb WF, Callaghan MW, Fuss S, Hilaire J, Creutzig F, del Mar Zamora Dominguez M. Negative emissions: Part 1: research landscape and synthesis. Environ Res Lett. 2018; 13 :063001. doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/aabf9b. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • O’Sullivan M, Overland I, Sandalow D (2017) The geopolitics of renewable energy, working paper, Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs, Harvard Kennedy School
  • OECD (2017) Closing the Regulatory Cycle: effective ex post evaluation for improved policy outcomes. In: 9th OECD conference on measuring regulatory performance, key findings and conference proceedings, http://www.oecd.org/gov/regulatory-policy/Proceedings-9th-Conference-MRP.pdf
  • Parry I (2015) Carbon Tax Burdens on Low-Income Households: A Reason for Delaying Climate Policy?, In: Clements B, de Mooij R, Gupta S, Keen M (2015) Inequality and Fiscal Policy, Ch. 13, International Monetary Fund, Washington
  • Pearce DW, Atkinson G, Dubourg WR. The economics of sustainable development. Annu Rev Energy Environ. 1994; 19 :457–474. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pellegrini L, Gerlagh R. Corruption, democracy, and environmental policy, an empirical contribution to the debate. J Environ Dev. 2008; 15 (3):332–354. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Peretto P (2017) Through scarcity to prosperity: a theory of the transition to sustainable growth, Economic Research Initiatives at Duke (ERID) Working Paper No. 260
  • Peretto P, Valente S. Growth on a finite planet: resources, technology and population in the long run. J Econ Growth. 2015; 20 (3):305–331. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pigou AC. The economics of welfare. London: Macmillan; 1920. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pindyck RS. Climate change policy: what do the models tell us? J Econ Literat. 2013; 51 :860–872. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pittel K, Rübbelke DTG. International climate finance and its influence on fairness and policy. World Econ. 2011; 36 (4):419–436. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Polasky SCL, Kling SA, Levin SR, Carpenter GC, Daily PR, Ehrlich GM Heal, Lubchenco J. Role of economics in analyzing the environment and sustainable development. PNAS. 2019; 116 (12):5233–5238. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Polyakov M, Chalak M, Iftekhar S, Pandit R, Tapsuwan S, Zhang F, Ma C. Authorship, collaboration, topics, and research gaps in environmental and resource economics 1991–2015. Environ Resource Econ. 2018; 71 (1):217–239. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pommeret A, Schubert K (2019) Energy transition with variable and intermittent renewable electricity generation, CESifo Working Paper Series 7442, CESifo Group Munich
  • Pommeret A, Schubert K. Intertemporal emission permits trading under uncertainty and irreversibility. Environ Resour Econ. 2018; 71 :73–97. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rockstrom J. A safe operating space for humanity. Nature. 2009; 461 :472–475. [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rodrik D. Second-best institutions. Am Econ Rev Paper Proc. 2008; 98 (2):100–104. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rozenberg J, Vogt-Schilb A, Hallegatte S. Instrument choice and stranded assets in the transition to clean capital. J Environ Econ Manage. 2020; 100 :102277. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Salzman J, Bennett G, Carroll N, Goldstein A, Jenkins M. The global status and trends of payments for ecosystem services. Nat Sustain. 2018; 1 :136–144. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Schirpke U, Tappeiner U, Tasser E. A transnational perspective of global and regional ecosystem service flows from and to mountain regions. Nature. 2019; 9 :6678. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Schlenker W, Walker RW. Airports. Air pollution, and contemporaneous health. Rev Econ Stud. 2016; 83 :768–809. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sen S, von Schickfus MT. Climate policy, stranded assets, and investors’ expectations. J Environ Econ Manage. 2020; 100 :102277. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Seto KC, Dhakai S, Bigio A, Delgado Arias S, Dewar D, Huang L, Ramaswami A (2014) Human settlements, infrastructure and spatial planning. In: Intergovernmental panel on climate change (eds.), Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
  • Small N, Munday M, Durance I. The challenge of valuing ecosystem services that have no material benefits. Glob Environ Change. 2017; 44 :57–67. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sovacool BK, Scarpaci J. Energy justice and the contested petroleum politics of stranded assets: Policy insights from the Yasun-ITT Initiative in Ecuador. Energy Policy. 2016; 95 :158–171. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stern N. The structure of economic modeling of the potential impacts of climate change: Grafting gross underestimation of risk onto already narrow science models. J Econ Literat. 2013; 51 (3):838–59. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stern N. Current climate models are grossly misleading. Nature. 2016; 530 :407–409. [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sterner T. Fuel taxes and the Poor: the distributional consequences of gasoline taxation and their implications for climate policy, Routledge Journals. New York: Taylor & Francis; 2011. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Stolbova V, Monasterolo I, Battiston S. A financial macro-network approach to climate policy evaluation. Ecol Econ C. 2018; 149 :239–253. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Strassheim H, Beck S. Handbook of behavioural change and public policy. Edward Elgar: Handbooks of Research on Public Policy series; 2019. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sulemanaa I, Nketiah-Amponsaha E, Codjoea EA, Andoh JAN. Urbanization and income inequality in Sub-Saharan Africa. Sustain Cities Soc. 2019; 48 :101544. doi: 10.1016/j.scs.2019.101544. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • TEEB (2020) The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity, https://www.teebweb.org
  • Tschofen P, Azevedo IL, Muller NZ. Fine particulate matter damages and value added in the US economy. PNAS. 2019; 116 (40):19857–19862. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • UN - United Nations (1992) Convention on biological diversity https://www.cbd.int/doc/legal/cbd-en.pdf
  • UN - United Nations (2015) Millenium Development Goals and Beyond 2015, Target 7, https://www.un.org/millenniumgoals/environ.shtml
  • UN - United Nations (2016) Urbanization and development: emerging futures, world cities report, http://wcr.unhabitat.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/02/WCR-2016-Full-Report.pdf
  • UN - United Nations (2018) 68% of the world population projected to live in urban areas by 2050, says UN, https://www.un.org/development/desa/en/news/population/2018-revision-of-world-urbanization-prospects.html
  • UN - United Nations (2019) World Population Prospects 2019: Highlights. UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division, New York
  • UNEP - United Nations Environmet Programme (2019), Emissions Gap Report 2019, Nairobi
  • Van der Ploeg F, de Zeeuw A. Climate tipping and economic growth: precautionary capital and the price of carbon. J Eur Econ Assoc. 2018; 16 (5):1577–1617. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Vatn A. An institutional analysis of payments for environmental services. Ecol Econ. 2010; 69 (6):1245–1252. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Verburg PH, Dearing JA, Dyke JG, van der Leeuw S, Seitzinger S, Steffen W, Syvitski J. Methods and approaches to modelling the Anthropocene. Glob Environ Change. 2016; 39 :328–340. [ Google Scholar ]
  • von Stechow C, Minx JC, Riahi K, Jewell J, McCollum DL, Callaghan MW, Bertram C, Luderer G, Baiocchi G. 2 ∘ C and SDGs: united they stand, divided they fall? Environ Res Lett. 2016; 11 :034022. doi: 10.1088/1748-9326/11/3/034022. [ CrossRef ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • WBGU - German Advisory Council on Global Change (2016) Humanity on the Move: Unlocking the transformative power of cities. WBGU, WBGU Flagship Report, Berlin
  • WBGU - German Advisory Council on Global Change (2018a) Just & In-Time Climate Policy. Four Initiatives for a Fair Transformation. Policy Paper 9. Berlin: WBGU
  • WBGU - German Advisory Council on Global Change (2018b) Towards our common digital future. WBGU, WBGU Flagship Report, Berlin
  • Weersink A, Fraser E, Pannell D, Duncan E, Rotz S. Opportunities and challenges for big data in agricultural and environmental analysis. Ann Rev Resour Econ. 2018; 10 :19–37. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Weitzman M. The Noah’s Ark approach. Econometrica. 1998; 66 (6):1279–1298. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Weitzman M. Book review on nature in the balance: the economics of biodiversity, edited by Dieter Helm and Cameron Hepburn. J Econ Literat. 2014; 52 (4):1193–1194. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Wunder S, Brouwer R, Engel S, Ezzine-de-Blas D, Muradian R, Pascual U, Pinto R. From principles to practice in paying for nature’s services. Nat Sustain. 2018; 1 :145–150. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Zhang P, Deschenes O, Meng K, Zhang J. Temperature effects on productivity and factor reallocation: Evidence from a half million Chinese manufacturing plants. J Environ Econ Manage. 2018; 88 :1–17. [ Google Scholar ]

UMBC logo with Maryland flag shield icon

  • Science & Tech

27th Summer Undergraduate Research Fest prepares students for scholarly next steps

Published: Aug 14, 2024

' src=

By: Sarah Hansen, M.S. '15

outdoor pedestrian corridor with a large group of professionally dressed students walking across; in foreground an easel with poster advertising Summer Undergraduate Research Fest that reads "SURF's UP 2024" at the top

In early August, 124 students from seven states and the District of Columbia participated in UMBC’s Summer Undergraduate Research Fest (SURF), sponsored by the College of Natural and Mathematical Sciences (CNMS). The students came from UMBC and other universities, community colleges, and three high schools, and they presented 106 posters and gave six “lightning talks” about research projects they completed over the summer. Almost all participants had completed their research under the mentorship of UMBC faculty.

CNMS Dean William R. LaCourse encouraged the students to carry their experience at UMBC with them after the summer ends. 

“I hope this summer has lit a flame of passion that will drive you to greater undertakings, accomplishments, and accolades. I hope that you did it all with joy and wonderment,” LaCourse said in his opening remarks at SURF. “It has been our privilege to host you here at UMBC—your spirit is an inspiration to us all. We hope that UMBC will always be a part of you.”

Members of the UMBC community and visitors interact with student researchers in a packed exhibition hall full of animated people and research posterboards on tables.

A grand scholarly community

SURF included student researchers involved in 14 different programs, such as the Howard Hughes Medical Institute HHMI Scholars Program, Beckman Scholars Program , National Science Foundation-funded Research Experiences for Undergraduates, and National Institutes of Health-funded research opportunities such as the U-RISE program and the National Institute on Drug Abuse internship.

Student projects included research on cancer biology, neuroscience, alternative energy, machine learning, and so much more. In addition to the presenters, their mentors, and members of the UMBC community at large, CNMS invited faculty members at other institutions affiliated with UMBC’s Build a Bridge to STEM Internship program to bring their students to SURF. Prince George’s Community College brought 15 students to observe, learn, and be inspired.

Four people sit at a table with a black tablecloth over it, one stands next to it, in front of a brick wall. All are dressed in black and gold and smiling.

The student research on display at SURF impressed Provost Manfred H.M. van Dulmen . “I truly enjoyed learning more about all the research being conducted on campus this summer, including how experimental research with flies can improve people’s lives,” van Dulmen shared after his first experience with SURF. “I loved talking to several students and learning about how their research experience plays a critical role in their education and prepares them for their future journey.”

Preparing students for their next steps is exactly what LaCourse hopes summer research and SURF will accomplish. “This event defines the summer STEM experience, where the focus is on high-quality STEM classes, opportunities for research and applied learning experiences, and building a strong scholarly STEM community,” he says. “By practicing and applying the skills of performing research this summer, you follow in the footsteps of great scientists and researchers—making you part of a grand scholarly community, and a community of support.”

Tags: CNMS , Research , Undergraduate Research

Related Posts

A girl with curly hair in a ponytail and a black t-shirt stands in front of a large building with paw prints on the Side and "Adoption Center"

Liz Willman ’25 uses internships to make childhood vet dreams a reality

  • Class of 2024
  • Policy & Society

Three college students in business suits stand with a college professor in a balcony with the U.S. Capitol behind them.

Peter Wilschke ’24, political science and economics, celebrates national research accomplishments

Black Farmers An adult with shoulder length brown hair wearing a blue blouse and a gold necklace stands outside in front of a building and orange stone arches. Researcher Loren Henderson

Academic Minute: Centering the voices of Black farmers

Want more umbc news, get top stories delivered to your inbox..

Sign up for our weekly UMBC Top Stories email :

Share a story idea and learn more about the news team.

Search UMBC Search

  • Accreditation
  • Consumer Information
  • Equal Opportunity
  • Privacy PDF Download
  • Web Accessibility

Search UMBC.edu

Careers at Virginia Tech

Postdoctoral research associate.

Apply now Back to search results Job no: 530570 Work type: Research Faculty Senior management: Agriculture & Life Sciences Department: Food Science and Technology Location: Blacksburg, Virginia Categories: Agriculture / Life Science

Job Description

The position is available beginning in September 2024. The successful candidate will primarily work on funded research projects to conduct techno-economic analysis and life cycle assessment to evaluate the economic and environmental aspects of novel processing technologies. The candidate will also work on bench experiments to convert food waste and processing byproducts into value-added products via chemical and biological pathways. The successful candidate will have opportunities to assist in writing research proposals to seek funding and mentoring graduate students.

Required Qualifications

Ph.D. in agricultural engineering, bioprocessing engineering, chemical engineering, food science and technology, environmental engineering, or other related disciplines awarded no more than four years prior to the effective date of the appointment with a minimum of one year of eligibility remaining; Self-motivated; Ability to work independently as well as collaboratively; Good oral and written communication skills.

Preferred Qualifications

Research experiences in techno-economic analysis, life cycle assessment, or process simulations Demonstrated a good publication record

Appointment Type

Salary Information

53,550-65,029

Review Date

Additional Information

The successful candidate will be required to have a criminal conviction check.

About Virginia Tech

Dedicated to its motto, Ut Prosim (That I May Serve), Virginia Tech pushes the boundaries of knowledge by taking a hands-on, transdisciplinary approach to preparing scholars to be leaders and problem-solvers. A comprehensive land-grant institution that enhances the quality of life in Virginia and throughout the world, Virginia Tech is an inclusive community dedicated to knowledge, discovery, and creativity. The university offers more than 280 majors to a diverse enrollment of more than 36,000 undergraduate, graduate, and professional students in eight undergraduate colleges , a school of medicine , a veterinary medicine college, Graduate School , and Honors College . The university has a significant presence across Virginia, including the Innovation Campus in Northern Virginia; the Health Sciences and Technology Campus in Roanoke; sites in Newport News and Richmond; and numerous Extension offices and research centers . A leading global research institution, Virginia Tech conducts more than $500 million in research annually.

Virginia Tech endorses and encourages participation in professional development opportunities and university shared governance .  These valuable contributions to university shared governance provide important representation and perspective, along with opportunities for unique and impactful professional development.

Virginia Tech does not discriminate against employees, students, or applicants on the basis of age, color, disability, sex (including pregnancy), gender, gender identity, gender expression, genetic information, ethnicity or national origin, political affiliation, race, religion, sexual orientation, or military status, or otherwise discriminate against employees or applicants who inquire about, discuss, or disclose their compensation or the compensation of other employees or applicants, or on any other basis protected by law.

If you are an individual with a disability and desire an accommodation, please contact Dr. Haibo Huang at [email protected] during regular business hours at least 10 business days prior to the event.

Advertised: August 16, 2024 Applications close:

Back to search results Apply now Refer a friend

We will email you new jobs that match this search.

Great, we can send you jobs like this, if this is your first time signing up, please check your inbox to confirm your subscription.

The email address was invalid, please check for errors.

You must agree to the privacy statement

Search results

Position Location Closes
Blacksburg, Virginia
The Food Science and Technology Department in the College of Agriculture and Life Sciences at Virginia Tech seeks a postdoctoral associate

Current opportunities

Expression of interest.

Powered by PageUp

IMAGES

  1. Research

    research areas in resource economics

  2. Research areas of CE research in the fields of business and economics

    research areas in resource economics

  3. PPT

    research areas in resource economics

  4. Environmental and resource economics: guidance on how to understand and

    research areas in resource economics

  5. Resource Economics

    research areas in resource economics

  6. Research focus areas › School of Business, Economics and Society

    research areas in resource economics

COMMENTS

  1. Research trends in environmental and resource economics: Insights from

    While up to about 10 years ago, non-market valuation and cost-benefit analysis, natural resource economics, and environmental policy instruments represented the lion's share of articles published in the journal, more recently we observe a significant shift towards a more diversified array of research areas, with climate change and energy issues ...

  2. Topics

    All NBER research is categorized into topic areas that collectively span the field of economics. Featured Topics. ... Environmental and Resource Economics. Agriculture. Renewable Resources. Energy. Environment. Regional and Urban Economics. ... National Bureau of Economic Research. Contact Us 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 617 ...

  3. Twenty Key Challenges in Environmental and Resource Economics

    Economic and ecological systems are closely interlinked at a global and a regional level, offering a broad variety of important research topics in environmental and resource economics. The successful identification of key challenges for current and future research supports development of novel theories, empirical applications, and appropriate policy designs. It allows establishing a future ...

  4. Annual Review of Resource Economics

    ISSN: 1941-1340. eISSN: 1941-1359. AIMS AND SCOPE OF JOURNAL: The Annual Review of Resource Economics provides authoritative critical reviews evaluating the most significant research developments in resource economics, focusing on agricultural economics, environmental economics, renewable resources, and exhaustible resources. Published Since.

  5. Research Areas

    Research Areas Environmental and Energy Economics. The energy, environment and resource field covers the economics of pollution, renewable and exhaustible resources with a focus on energy. ... The first two courses in the field include the fundamentals of resource economics including the classic Hotelling problem, both theory and empirical ...

  6. Research Areas

    Development EconomicsAmong the world poor, nearly 70% are rural, and agriculture and natural resources play an important role in their livelihoods. As a consequence, there is much demand for the contributions of economists and agricultural economists in helping to devise and implement solutions. We prepare students to address these issues through research, teaching, project development, and ...

  7. Annual Review of Resource Economics

    Ecosystem restoration should be among our main scientific endeavors. This review fills a critical gap in the existing literature by providing a theory-informed understanding of the findings emerging from this highly policy-relevant strand of resource economics. The article also suggests key areas for future research.

  8. Home

    The European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (EAERE) is an international scientific association which aims are:- to contribute to the development and application of environmental and resource economics as a science in Europe;- to encourage and improve communication between teachers, researchers and students in environmental and resource economics in different European ...

  9. Research Trends in Environmental and Resource Economics: Insights from

    While up to about 10 years ago, non-m arket valuation and cost-benefit analysis, natural resource economics, and environmental policy instruments represented the lion's share of articles published in the journal, more recently we observe a significant shift towards a more diversified array of research areas, with climate change and energy ...

  10. Resource and Environmental Economics : Modern Issues and Applications

    Natural resource economics (previously known as land economics) emerged as a focus of interest in the early development of economics. Sometimes the French physiocrats (writing about the mid-1700s) are credited with being the pioneers of natural resource economics (see Cleveland, 2010). Possibly, Quesnay (1694-1774) is the most widely known ...

  11. Research Overview

    Research. Faculty in the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics conduct research, data analysis, and forecast modeling related to local and global agricultural industries, natural resource economics, trade, and development economics in countries around the world. As part of the University of Arizona's Land Grant Mission, we also ...

  12. Environmental, Resource and Energy Economics

    Landau Economics Building. 579 Jane Stanford Way. Stanford, CA 94305. Phone: 650-725-3266. [email protected]. Campus Map. "The Stanford Economics Department has two central missions: to train students at the undergraduate and graduate level in the methods and ideas of modern economics, and to conduct both basic and applied research in economics ...

  13. Natural resource economics

    Natural resource economics is a transdisciplinary field of academic research within economics that aims to address the connections and interdependence between human economies and natural ecosystems. ... The economics and policy area focuses on the human aspects of environmental problems. ... Research topics could include the environmental ...

  14. Research Areas

    Environmental and Energy Economics. Environmental and energy economics concerns the economics of environmental quality, natural resource management, and energy production and regulation. Critical policy questions include climate change, air quality, valuation of environmental amenities, and the design of effective regulation.

  15. Research

    Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 88 (March): 411-426, 2018. The Economic Cost of Unanticipated Water Supply Reductions for Agricultural Producers in the Humboldt River Region. Journal of the Nevada Water Resources Association, Winter 2021, p. 5-41. DOI: 10.22542/jnwra/2021/1/1.

  16. Natural Resource and Environmental Economics Research

    Dr. Paul Huszar's research in the natural resources/environmental economics area entails both domestic and international projects. Most recently, his domestic work has been concerned with the non-consumptive use of agricultural water. Prior to that his work concerned off-site costs of wind erosion. Internationally, his recent work has been on ...

  17. Research Areas

    Natural Resource and Environmental Economics. Because California faces some of the more pressing conflicts between agriculture, urban growth, and the natural environment, UC Davis provides an ideal physical location to study resource and environmental issues. ... In each research area in the department, faculty and students apply state-of-the ...

  18. Erik Katovich

    PhD in Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 2022. ... Research Areas. Environmental and Resource Economics. Development Economics. Political Economy . Teaching. ARE 2250. Energy Economics: Sustainable Transitions (available Fall 2025) ARE 6203. Economics Methodology: Praxis and Practice. ARE 5495/6695. Global ...

  19. Studies in Energy, Resource and Environmental Economics

    This book series offers an outlet for cutting-edge research on all areas of energy, environmental and resource economics. The series welcomes theoretically sound and empirically robust monographs and edited volumes, as well as textbooks and handbooks from various disciplines and approaches on topics such as energy and resource markets, the economics of climate change, environmental evaluation ...

  20. Natural Resource and Environmental Economics

    The Food and Resource Economics Department (FRED) focuses on teaching, research, and extension related to the food and agricultural systems in Florida. ... Research Areas. Natural Resource and Environmental Economics. FRE faculty apply methodologies such as ecosystem service valuation, cost-benefit analysis of policy interventions, bioeconomic ...

  21. Transportation Research Board

    Learn about the Transportation Research Board, a division of the National Academies that provides leadership and innovation in transportation research and policy.

  22. Research Areas

    Agricultural and Resource Policy At the department's inception, farm management was the main area of emphasis in ARE. Over time, our department has diversified and modernized, and our research in the area of agricultural and resource economics has expanded well beyond this initial focus.

  23. Best-Performing Cities 2024: Focus on Sustainable Growth and Resilience

    The Best-Performing Cities (BPC) 2024 rankings evaluate the performance of 403 metropolitan areas across the US based on 13 indicators that cover labor market conditions, high-tech impact, and access to economic opportunities. As the post-pandemic economy reaches a new status quo, metropolitan areas remain at the heart of the nation's growth.

  24. Australia's National Science and Research Priorities

    We have also identified critical research needed in the next 5 to 10 years to achieve these outcomes. Priority 1: Transitioning to a net zero future Where we want to be . Science and research will help Australia take the technological leaps needed to achieve a net zero economy by 2050, with emissions levels 43% below 2005 levels by 2030.

  25. Twenty Key Challenges in Environmental and Resource Economics

    The research agenda in environmental and resource economics has always been very broad and dynamic, reflecting the ways our economies interact with the natural environment. While in classical economics of the eighteenth century the factor land played a dominant role, the effects of pollution externalities, resource scarcities, ecosystem ...

  26. 27th Summer Undergraduate Research Fest Prepares Students For Scholarly

    In early August, 124 students from seven states and the District of Columbia participated in UMBC's Summer Undergraduate Research Fest (SURF), sponsored by the College of Natural and Mathematical Sciences (CNMS). The students came from UMBC and other universities, community colleges, and three high schools, and they presented 106 posters and gave six "lightning talks" about research ...

  27. Details

    A leading global research institution, Virginia Tech conducts more than $500 million in research annually. Virginia Tech endorses and encourages participation in professional development opportunities and university shared governance. These valuable contributions to university shared governance provide important representation and perspective ...

  28. Credit Cards: The Trillion-Dollar Debt

    "Highest Credit Card Debt in History" was US headline news in early August 2023. This is quite a change from credit card debt during the pandemic, when reduced consumer spending led to a large drop in average credit card balances. 1 After reaching an all-time high and exceeding $1 trillion in the second quarter of 2023, credit card debt and usage moved into the spotlight.